07.09.2017 Views

David K.H. Begg, Gianluigi Vernasca-Economics-McGraw Hill Higher Education (2011)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

26.6 Growth in the OECD<br />

II : e!p ;: ctatro: s :co. :na !or people earning only<br />

y save sy and consume (1 - s)y. But if y is low enough, (1 - s)y is too low to stop starvation.<br />

So they consume all their income and save none. Below a critical income level y0, saving is zero. What<br />

does the Solow diagram look like now? See diagram below. Suppose k0 is the capital per person that just<br />

generates the critical income Yo· <strong>Higher</strong> capital generates saving as in previous diagrams, and nk is still the<br />

gross investment needed to maintain a given capital-labour ratio in the face of growing population. There are<br />

now three steady states!<br />

If capital begins above k 1 the economy converges to the steady state at E. Between k1 and k2, saving and investment<br />

exceed the amount needed for capital widening: capital-deepening also occurs and the economy grows. Above<br />

k2, saving and investment are insufficient to maintain the capital-labour ratio, and the economy shrinks. Either<br />

way it ends at E. This is the case analysed in Figures 26.2 and 26.3. Suppose, next, the economy begins at exactly<br />

k1• Saving and investment just maintain the capital-labour ratio. So this is a steady state, but an unstable one.<br />

A little above k1 the economy begins converging<br />

on E. And below k1 there is insufficient saving<br />

and investment to provide for the growing<br />

nk<br />

population. Capital per person shrinks and keeps<br />

shrinking until the economy reaches k = 0.<br />

In this model, countries beginning with capital<br />

below k1 are stuck in a poverty trap. They<br />

cannot break out. All output is consumed to<br />

prevent starvation. There is never a surplus to<br />

begin accumulation and growth. This model<br />

can also explain why convergence seems to<br />

occur within the OECD (countries already<br />

above k1), but why simultaneously many countries<br />

are stuck in poverty. Modern growth in<br />

the last two centuries began when some key<br />

events first generated the surplus to allow<br />

saving and accumulation to begin.<br />

Questions<br />

(a) Why is there no poverty trap when saving is proportional to income?<br />

y<br />

(b) When a poverty trap exists, is the payoff to overseas aid from rich countries greater if it is concentrated<br />

on helping poor countries break out of the poverty trap?<br />

(c) The poverty trap shown above is based on there being a minimum level of per capita consumption.<br />

Could we get a poverty trap based on different population growth rates above and below some critical<br />

threshold of living standards? Is this plausible?<br />

To check your answers to these questions, go to page 688.<br />

0<br />

k<br />

Neither the internet boom nor supply-side reforms restored the productivity growth rates that the rich<br />

countries enjoyed prior to 1973. Emerging market economies, such as China, India, Brazil and Russia, are<br />

now where the action is. We turn to their story in Part Five. For rich mature economies, Table 26.2 confirms<br />

that underlying productivity growth showed a modest improvement after 1990, until it was dramatically<br />

interrupted by recession after the financial crash.<br />

603

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!