07.09.2017 Views

David K.H. Begg, Gianluigi Vernasca-Economics-McGraw Hill Higher Education (2011)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

7. 7 Returns to scale<br />

Scale economies and the internet<br />

Producing information products such as films, music and news programmes has a high fixed<br />

cost, but distributing these products digitally has almost a zero marginal cost and no capacity<br />

constraint. Scale economies are vast. Moreover, if marginal cost is close to zero, smart suppliers will price<br />

their products so that marginal revenue is also tiny.<br />

EMI, a legend of the music industry, was formed in 1931. Its Abbey Road studios in London hosted giants<br />

such as the Beatles. Moving with the times, EMI has steadily withdrawn from the business of supplying<br />

records and CDs, and now operates largely online. In April 2007, EMI announced it would begin releasing its<br />

music as superior-quality tracks available exclusively on the iTunes Store. Costing £0.99, the tracks were to be<br />

free of restrictions on access and distribution, and no longer utilized anti-copying software. Lower-quality<br />

tracks with restrictions were to be sold for £0.79.<br />

Diseconomies of scale<br />

Beyond some output, the U-shaped average cost curve turns up again as diseconomies<br />

of scale begin. Management is harder as the firm gets larger: there are<br />

managerial diseconomies of scale. Large companies need many layers of management,<br />

themselves needing to be managed. The company becomes bureaucratic,<br />

co-ordination problems arise and average costs begin to rise.<br />

Diseconomies of scale<br />

(or decreasing returns to<br />

scale) mean long-run average<br />

cost rises as output rises.<br />

Geography may also explain diseconomies of scale. If the first factory is located in the best site, to minimize<br />

the cost of transporting goods to the market, the site of a second factory must be less advantageous. To take<br />

a different example, in extracting coal from a mine, a firm will extract the easiest coal first. To increase<br />

output, deeper coal seams have to be worked and these will be more expensive.<br />

As output increases, the shape of the average cost curve thus depends on two things: how long economies<br />

of scale persist and how quickly the diseconomies of scale set in. The balance of these two forces varies<br />

from industry to industry and from firm to firm.<br />

The long-run production function and the returns to scale<br />

II<br />

We defined the returns to scale in terms of the relationship between the long-run average cost<br />

and the level of output. We can define the same concepts using the relationship between inputs<br />

and output implied by a long-run production function.<br />

We say that a production function displays increasing, constant or decreasing returns to scale if the following<br />

definitions hold:<br />

(a) Increasing returns to scale (or economies of scale): when all the inputs of production are increased by the<br />

same factor and the output produced increases more than proportionally.<br />

(b) Constant returns to scale: when all the inputs of production are<br />

increased by the same factor and the output produced increases by the<br />

same factor.<br />

Constant returns to scale<br />

mean long-run average costs<br />

are constant as output rises.<br />

(c) Decreasing returns to scale (or diseconomies of scale): when all the inputs of production are increased by<br />

the same factor and the output produced increases less than proportionally.<br />

0<br />

161

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!