07.09.2017 Views

David K.H. Begg, Gianluigi Vernasca-Economics-McGraw Hill Higher Education (2011)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

17 .2 Government and aggregate demand<br />

than was necessary. When global financial meltdown began in 2008/09, governments thought they had<br />

learned this lesson, and threw the kitchen sink at fixing the banks.<br />

By early 2010, many of the banks seemed to have come back from the brink. The chart opposite shows the<br />

share price of Royal Bank of Scotland, in which, during 2009, the government had to take an 84 per cent stake<br />

in order to avert its collapse. Its share price having fallen from 400 pence to I 0 pence, it then seemed to<br />

stabilize around 30-50 pence thereafter.<br />

Improved private sector solvency has come at the price of reduced solvency for the government that<br />

injected all the money. Whether the government can cope with its high debt burden is a subject to which<br />

we return.<br />

This leads to the third lesson from Japan. If pressing the fiscal accelerator is difficult once the government is<br />

heavily indebted, the monetary accelerator must be flat on the floor. Japanese monetary policy eventually cut<br />

interest rates to zero. Having learned from this experience, central banks in the US, the UK and eurozone<br />

slashed interest rates to very low levels in 2009 when aggregate demand and output began to plummet.<br />

The multiplier revisited<br />

The multiplier relates changes in autonomous demand to changes in equilibrium income and output. The<br />

formula in Chapter 16 still applies, provided we use MPC', the marginal propensity to consume out of<br />

gross, rather than out of disposable, income.<br />

Multiplier = 1/ (I -<br />

MPC') (1)<br />

With proportional taxes, MPC' equals MPC x (1 - t). For a given marginal propensity to consume out of<br />

disposable income, a higher tax rate t reduces MPC', raises (I - MPC') and so reduces the multiplier. The<br />

more the circular flow leaks out into taxation, the less flows round again to stimulate further expansion of<br />

output and income. Table 17 .2 illustrates.<br />

In Chapter 16, without government the multiplier was simply 1/(1 - MPC) or I/MPS. With a larger<br />

marginal propensity to save, there was a larger leakage from the circular flow between firms and households,<br />

and the multiplier was correspondingly smaller.<br />

Table 17.2 merely extends this insight. Now leakages arise both from saving and from net taxes. When<br />

both are large, the multiplier is small. The bottom row of the table has a much smaller multiplier than the<br />

top row.<br />

Table 17.2<br />

Values of the multiplier<br />

MPC<br />

T<br />

MPC'<br />

Multiplier<br />

0.9 0<br />

0.9 0.2<br />

0.7 0<br />

0.7 0.2<br />

0.7 0.4<br />

0.90 10.00<br />

0.72 3.57<br />

0.70 3.33<br />

0.56 2.27<br />

0.42 1.72<br />

405

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!