07.09.2017 Views

David K.H. Begg, Gianluigi Vernasca-Economics-McGraw Hill Higher Education (2011)

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

5.3 Adjustment to price changes<br />

implies a negative relationship between the quantity<br />

demanded of that good and its market price.<br />

y<br />

Inferior goods<br />

Although the substitution effect must reduce the<br />

quantity of meals demanded when the price of meals<br />

increases, the income effect goes in the opposite<br />

direction if the good is inferior: reductions in real<br />

income increase the quantity demanded. We can<br />

even imagine a perverse case in which this effect is<br />

so strong that price rises actually increase the<br />

quantity of that good demanded. Demand curves<br />

then slope upwards! We can use our analysis to<br />

explain how such a paradoxical case can arise.<br />

Consider the case of two different goods, X and Y.<br />

This is represented in Figure 5.15. Suppose that the<br />

price of good X decreases. As usual after a price<br />

change we can decompose the effect of this price<br />

change into substitution and income effects. Suppose<br />

that before the decrease in the price of X the optimal<br />

Income effect Substitution effect<br />

A Giffen good is an inferior good for which the income effect is<br />

positive and larger than the substitution effect (always negative).<br />

Figure 5.15 A Giffen good<br />

choice of the consumer was bundle C on the indifference curve U1 U1• After the price of X decreases, the<br />

budget constraint rotates outwards from AF to AF'. The new choice of the consumer is bundle E on the<br />

indifference curve U2 U2. To show the income and substitution effects, we draw a new budget line HH<br />

parallel to AF' and tangent to the original indifference curve ( U1 U1). By doing this, we identify bundle D.<br />

The movement from C to D is due to the substitution effect. Since the price of X decreased, good Xis now<br />

relatively cheaper than good Y and so the consumer substitutes Y with X. The movement from D to E is<br />

due to the income effect. As income increases, the quantity demanded of good X decreases (from xD to xE).<br />

In this case, Xis an inferior good. For an inferior good, it is always true that income and substitution effects<br />

go in opposite directions. In the particular case considered in Figure 5.15, the income effect is larger than<br />

the substitution effect and the final result is that, after the price of X has decreased, the quantity demanded<br />

of X has decreased (from Xe to xE). In this case, the demand curve of good Xis upward sloping.<br />

A good that has such a property (the income effect is bigger than the substitution effect) is called a Giffen<br />

good, after a nineteenth-century economist who examined whether higher potato prices raised the quantity<br />

of potatoes demanded by the poor.<br />

Notice in Figure 5.15 that, while good Xis a Giffen good, Yis instead a normal good. As income increases,<br />

the quantity demanded of Y increases.<br />

An inferior good need not be a Giffen good. It requires a very strong income effect - here, an increase in demand<br />

in response to real income reductions - to offset the substitution effect that is always negative. When goods<br />

are inferior, theoretical reasoning cannot establish which effect dominates. We must look at the empirical<br />

evidence. After decades of empirical research, economists are convinced that Giffen goods are rare. In practice,<br />

goods are rarely so inferior that the income effect can reverse the substitution effect. This means that, apart<br />

from the rare cases given by Giffen goods, for almost all goods we should have a negative demand curve.<br />

Cross-price elasticities of demand<br />

How does a rise in the price of one good affect demand for other goods? Chapter 4 showed that cross-price<br />

elasticities may be negative or positive. We now illustrate these possibilities, highlighting the roles played<br />

by substitution and income effects.<br />

F'<br />

x<br />

109

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!