07.09.2017 Views

David K.H. Begg, Gianluigi Vernasca-Economics-McGraw Hill Higher Education (2011)

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

CHAPTER 22 Inflation, expectations and credibility<br />

Table 22.1 The German hyperinflation, 1922-23<br />

Money<br />

Prices<br />

Real money<br />

Inflation % monthly<br />

January 1922 1 1<br />

January 1923 16 75<br />

-<br />

-<br />

July 1923 354 2021<br />

September 1923 227 777 645946<br />

-<br />

-<br />

October 1 923 20 201 256 191 891 890<br />

-<br />

1.00 5<br />

0.21 189<br />

0.18 386<br />

0.35 2532<br />

0.11 29 720<br />

Source: Data adapted from Holtfrerish, C. L. (1 980) Die Deutsche Inflation 1914-23, Walter de Gruyter.<br />

The flight from cash is the<br />

collapse in the demand for<br />

real cash when high inflation<br />

and high nominal interest rates<br />

make it very expensive to hold<br />

cash.<br />

People, paid twice a day, shopped in their lunch hour before the real value of<br />

their cash depreciated too much. Any cash not immediately spent was quickly<br />

deposited in a bank where it could earn interest. People spent a lot of time at the<br />

bank.<br />

What lessons can we draw? First, rising inflation and rising interest rates<br />

significantly reduce the demand for real cash. Hyperinflations are a rare example<br />

in which a real quantity (real cash) changes quickly and by a lot. Second, and as<br />

a result, money and prices can get quite out of line when inflation and nominal interest rates are rising.<br />

Table 22.1 shows that prices rose by six times as much as nominal money between January 1922 and July<br />

1923, reducing the real money supply by 82 per cent, in line with the fall in real money demand - a<br />

flight from cash .<br />

( Inflation, money and deficits<br />

..,_ _ _ _ _<br />

Persistent inflation must be accompanied by continuing nominal money growth. Printing money to<br />

finance a large deficit is a source of inflation. Budget deficits may explain why governments have to print<br />

money rapidly. If so, tight fiscal policy is needed to fight inflation.<br />

The level of GDP affects how much tax revenue the government gets at given tax rates. If government debt<br />

is low relative to GDP, the government can finance deficits by borrowing. It has enough tax revenue with<br />

which to pay interest and repay the debt. For governments with low debt, there may be no relation between<br />

their budget deficit and how much money they print. Sometimes they print money; sometimes they issue<br />

bonds. We do not expect a close relationship between deficits and money creation in a country like the UK.<br />

Nevertheless, many years of deficits may make government debt large relative to GDP. The government<br />

can no longer finance deficits by more borrowing. It then has to tighten fiscal policy to shrink the deficit,<br />

or print money to finance the continuing deficit.<br />

To ensure that the European Central Bank did not face fiscal pressure to print too much money and thus<br />

create inflation, members of the eurozone had to obey the Stability and Growth Pact, which restricts their<br />

budget deficits to less than 3 per cent of GDP, except in severe recession. Of course, when severe recession<br />

arrived in 2009, budget deficits escalated to 10 per cent and beyond. We never quite know how binding a<br />

commitment will be until a crisis occurs. Similarly, the UK's Code for Fiscal Stability committed the UK<br />

government to not keep running big deficits that steadily raise government debt relative to GDP. When it<br />

came to the crunch, this commitment was (wisely) jettisoned.<br />

506

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!