07.09.2017 Views

David K.H. Begg, Gianluigi Vernasca-Economics-McGraw Hill Higher Education (2011)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

CHAPTER 20 Monetary and fiscal policy<br />

-<br />

.,<br />

Monetary policy<br />

_ _ _ _ _<br />

Economists distinguish between rules and discretion. A smoker decides from minute to minute whether<br />

to have a cigarette. Once we understand his preferences, the price of cigarettes, his income, and the attitude<br />

of his friends, we can model his behaviour and predict pretty accurately how he will behave since this is<br />

consistently related to the environment that he faces, even though he has discretion or freedom to decide<br />

how much to smoke.<br />

A rule is a commitment<br />

describing how behaviour<br />

changes when circumstances<br />

change.<br />

Discretion means free<br />

choice without restrictions<br />

imposed by prior<br />

commitments.<br />

A rule is a commitment on how to behave, for example to smoke no more than ten<br />

cigarettes a day. This rule is credible only if we understand what prevents the<br />

smoker having the eleventh cigarette when he desperately wants one. Being<br />

abandoned by his friends if he smokes more than ten might be a commitment<br />

mechanism to enforce the rule. A rule constrains his discretion, limits his freedom,<br />

and precludes the choice he would otherwise have made.<br />

What do we mean by a given monetary policy? This has two aspects. First, to what<br />

variable does it refer - the interest rate or the money supply? For the reasons given<br />

in the previous two chapters, we prefer to focus on the interest rate.<br />

Second, does a given policy mean the choice of a particular interest rate? Changing the interest rate would<br />

then be a change in policy. This is simple, but we can do better. We can usually model why that interest rate<br />

was chosen: the relationship between the chosen interest rate and other economic variables. A particular<br />

monetary policy is then a particular relationship rather than a particular interest<br />

A particular monetary policy<br />

is a relationship between the<br />

state of the economy and the<br />

interest rate chosen by the<br />

central bank.<br />

rate. This relationship may reflect discretionary choices of the central bank or a<br />

commitment to a particular rule. Either way, a change in monetary policy is then<br />

a change in the relationship between the chosen interest rate and the economic<br />

circumstances faced by the central bank.<br />

Thus interest rates change either because economic circumstances change (within<br />

a given monetary policy) or because the central bank switches to a different<br />

preferred relationship between interest rates and the state of the economy (a change in monetary policy).<br />

In the heyday of monetarism, central banks used to adjust interest rates to stop the money supply deviating<br />

from a given target path of monetary growth. Most central banks have abandoned this policy, preferring<br />

to target the inflation rate itself.<br />

Following a monetary<br />

target, the central banks<br />

adjust interest rates to<br />

maintain the quantity of money<br />

demanded in line with the<br />

given target for money supply.<br />

Inflation targeting makes no sense in a model in which we still assume prices are<br />

fixed. We introduce inflation targeting in Chapter 21. In this chapter, we assume<br />

instead that the central bank pursues a monetary target. This is a good way to<br />

introduce many key ideas, and is useful in understanding how monetary policy<br />

was set in the 1980s before inflation targeting became popular.<br />

We now combine our analysis of the goods market and money market to examine<br />

interest rates and output simultaneously. Chapters 16 and 17 analysed shortrun<br />

equilibrium output using a diagram with the 45° line and a straight-line aggregate demand line. The<br />

height of the aggregate demand line reflected autonomous demand from consumption, investment and<br />

government spending; the slope of the line reflected the marginal propensity to spend out of national<br />

income.<br />

This diagram is not suitable in our extended model. As output changes, interest rates alter, affecting<br />

consumption and investment demand. And changes in monetary policy, by changing interest rates at any<br />

output level, can shift the aggregate demand schedule. To keep track of all these effects, it is easier to<br />

develop a new diagram.<br />

464

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!