07.09.2017 Views

David K.H. Begg, Gianluigi Vernasca-Economics-McGraw Hill Higher Education (2011)

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

CHAPTER 5 Consumer choice and demand decisions<br />

8<br />

II) 7<br />

.5 6<br />

ii: 5<br />

4<br />

3<br />

2<br />

1<br />

0 2 4 6 8<br />

Meals<br />

F'<br />

12 14 16 QM<br />

Again, income is increased from £50 to £80 and there<br />

is a parallel shift in the budget line from AF to A'F'. If<br />

meals were an inferior good, the quantity demanded<br />

would fall as income rises. The consumer then moves<br />

from C to C' when income rises.<br />

Figure 5.10 An increase in income reduces<br />

demand for the inferior good<br />

y<br />

Figure 5.11<br />

goods<br />

Income expansion path for normal<br />

x<br />

To find the exact position of this new line, we again<br />

calculate the end-points at which all income is spent<br />

on a single good. Point A shows that £80 buys at most<br />

8 films at £10 each. Point F shows that £80 buys at<br />

most 16 meals at £5 each. Joining these points yields<br />

the new budget line A'F'. Since the slope of a budget line<br />

depends only on the relative price of the two goods,<br />

which is unchanged, the new budget line A' F' is parallel<br />

to the old budget line AF. Which point on A'F'will the<br />

student choose? She chooses C', at which the new budget<br />

line is tangent to the highest attainable indifference<br />

curve. However, the position of C' depends on the map<br />

of indifference curves that describe her tastes.<br />

For most consumers, food is a normal good but a<br />

necessity, whereas films are a luxury. Figure 5.9 shows<br />

the case in which her tastes have these properties.<br />

A rise in income from £50 to £80 moves her from C<br />

(2 films, 6 meals) to C' (4 films, 8 meals). Thus, a<br />

60 per cent rise in income induces a 100 per cent<br />

increase in the quantity of films demanded, confirming<br />

that films are a luxury good with income elasticity in<br />

excess of unity. Similarly, the 60 per cent rise in income<br />

induces a 33 per cent increase in the quantity of<br />

meals demanded. The income elasticity of demand for<br />

food is (0.33/0.6) = 0.55, confirming that food is a<br />

normal good (income elasticity greater than zero)<br />

but a necessity (income elasticity less than unity).<br />

In contrast, in Figure 5.10 her tastes make food an<br />

inferior good, for which the quantity demanded declines<br />

as income rises. At point C' on the budget line A'F',<br />

fewer meals are demanded than at point C on the<br />

budget line AF, corresponding to the lower income.<br />

The effects of a fall in income are, of course, exactly<br />

the opposite. The budget line shifts inwards but remains<br />

parallel to the original budget line. When both goods<br />

are normal, lower consumer income reduces the<br />

quantity demanded for both goods. If one good is<br />

inferior, the quantity demanded will actually rise if<br />

income falls. Notice that both goods cannot be inferior:<br />

when income falls but prices remain unchanged it<br />

cannot be feasible for the consumer to consume more<br />

of both goods.<br />

The income expansion<br />

path shows how the chosen<br />

bundle of goods varies with<br />

consumer income levels,<br />

keeping constant everything<br />

else.<br />

Income expansion paths<br />

Instead of the response of demand to a particular change in income, we might<br />

want to know the response of demand to income in relation to all possible<br />

variations in income. To study this, we trace out the income expansion path. Look<br />

again at Figure 5.9. The budget lines AF and A'F' correspond to incomes of £50<br />

104

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!