07.09.2017 Views

David K.H. Begg, Gianluigi Vernasca-Economics-McGraw Hill Higher Education (2011)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

28.4 The economics of tariffs<br />

SS<br />

Q)<br />

"<br />

.i::<br />

A.<br />

£12 000<br />

L<br />

World price<br />

plus tariff<br />

£10 000 J World price<br />

1<br />

: -. : +--<br />

I<br />

I<br />

Qs Q' s Q Qd<br />

Quantity<br />

The tariff leads to both transfers and to net social losses. The tariff raises the domestic price from £10 000<br />

to £12 000. LFHJ shows extra consumer payments of the Q cars they now buy. But EFHI is a transfer to the<br />

government and ECJL is a transfer to extra profits of producers. Areas A and B are pure waste and net social<br />

losses. Triangle A is the extra that society spends by producing cars domestically instead of importing them at<br />

the world price. Triangle Bis the excess of consumer benefits over social marginal cost that society sacrifices<br />

by reducing its consumption of cars from Qd to Q.<br />

I<br />

Figure 28.4<br />

The welfare costs of a tariff<br />

By raising domestic car prices, the tariff boosts domestic car production from Qs to Q/. The tariff protects<br />

domestic producers by raising the domestic price at which imports become competitive. In moving up the<br />

supply curve from C to E, domestic producers with marginal costs between £10 000 and £12 000 can now<br />

survive at the higher domestic price of cars.<br />

The higher price also moves consumers up their demand curve from G to F. The quantity of cars demanded<br />

falls from Qd to Q;. For consumers, the tariff is like a tax. Cars cost more.<br />

Figure 28.3 shows the combined effect of higher domestic production but lower domestic consumption.<br />

Imports fall because domestic production rises and because domestic consumption falls. The more elastic<br />

are these supply and demand schedules, the more a given tariff reduces imports. If both schedules are very<br />

steep, the quantity of imports hardly changes.<br />

Costs and benefits of a tariff<br />

Figure 28.4 shows the costs and benefits of imposing a tariff. We distinguish net costs to society from<br />

transfers between one part of the economy and another.<br />

After the tariff is imposed, consumers buy the quantity Q;. Since the consumer price rises by £2000,<br />

consumers spend (£2000 x Q;) more than before to buy the quantity Q;. Who gets these extra payments<br />

- the area LFHJ in Figure 28.4?<br />

Some of the extra consumer payments go to the government, whose revenue from the tariff is the rectangle<br />

EFHI, the tariff of £2000 per imported car times ( Qd- Q;) the number of imported cars. This transfer EFHI<br />

from consumers to government is not a net cost to society. For example, the government can use the tariff<br />

revenue to reduce income tax rates.<br />

647

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!