07.09.2017 Views

David K.H. Begg, Gianluigi Vernasca-Economics-McGraw Hill Higher Education (2011)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

CHAPTER 13 Welfare economics<br />

have considered private goods. Private goods are those that can be consumed only by the buyer. For<br />

example, if you buy a can of Coke, you pay for it and you drink it. Other consumers cannot drink the same can<br />

of Coke. In contrast to private goods, public goods are those that, if consumed by one person, must be<br />

consumed by others in exactly the same quantity. For example, national defence. Since you get the same<br />

quantity of national defence as everyone else, whether or not you pay for it, you never buy national defence in<br />

a private market. Therefore, in the case of public goods, we have goods that society would like to consume<br />

but the private market mechanism cannot provide (or will underprovide). Taxes and public goods are<br />

analysed in detail in Chapter 14.<br />

Externalities<br />

Externalities are things like pollution, noise and congestion. One person's actions have direct costs or<br />

benefits for other people, but the individual does not take these into account. Much of the rest of this<br />

chapter examines this distortion. The problem arises because there is no market for things like noise.<br />

Hence markets and prices cannot ensure that the marginal benefit you get from making a noise equals the<br />

marginal cost of that noise to other people.<br />

Asymmetric information<br />

In Chapter 12 we saw how moral hazard and adverse selection inhibit the setting up of insurance markets<br />

to deal with risk. The fact that there exists imperfect information in certain markets may lead to a failure<br />

in such markets.<br />

Under asymmetric information, one party in a market transaction has more information than the other<br />

party. For example, a seller may know the true quality of the good she is selling while the buyer does not.<br />

Suppose that buyers want to buy used cars. There are various sellers in the market, some selling highquality<br />

used cars some selling low-quality cars. If the buyers cannot tell the difference between low and<br />

high quality, they will probably be unwilling to pay much for a used car (they always face the possibility of<br />

getting a low-quality used car). As a result, the sellers with high-quality used cars may end up selling them<br />

at a price that is lower than their value, meaning it is unprofitable for those sellers to stay in the market. In<br />

practice, under asymmetric information, the existence of the low-quality product drives the high-quality<br />

product out of the market. This is a market failure since the market for the high-quality product is<br />

eliminated even if the buyers value it at more than the cost of producing it.<br />

The case of used cars is known as the market for 'lemons' (whereby lemons means the low-quality used<br />

cars) - a typical example of adverse selection.<br />

Ai Externalities<br />

-<br />

- - - -<br />

An externality arises if<br />

one person's production or<br />

consumption physically affects<br />

the production or consumption<br />

of others.<br />

A chemical firm discharges waste into a lake, polluting the water. It affects the<br />

production of anglers (fewer fish, harder to catch) or the consumption of swimmers<br />

(dirty water). Without a 'market' for pollution, the firm can pollute the lake without<br />

cost. Its self-interest leads it to pollute until the marginal benefit of polluting (cheaper<br />

production of chemicals) equals its own marginal cost of polluting, which is zero.<br />

It ignores the marginal cost that pollution imposed on anglers and swimmers.<br />

Conversely, by painting your house you make the whole street look nicer and give consumption benefits<br />

to your neighbour. But you paint only up to the point on which your own marginal benefit equals the<br />

marginal cost of the paint you buy and the time you spend. Your marginal costs are also society's marginal<br />

costs, but society's marginal benefits exceed your own. Hence, there is too little house painting.<br />

316

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!