07.09.2017 Views

David K.H. Begg, Gianluigi Vernasca-Economics-McGraw Hill Higher Education (2011)

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

29.6 Antecedents of the eurozone<br />

policy in EMU was to be set by an independent central bank, mandated to achieve price stability as its<br />

principal goal.<br />

There were two sets of criteria, one for monetary policy and nominal variables and one for fiscal policy.<br />

The monetary criteria said that, to be eligible, a potential entrant had to have low inflation, low nominal interest<br />

rates (market confirmation oflow inflation expectations) and two prior years in the ERM without any devaluation.<br />

This last requirement was to prevent competitive devaluations or 'last realignments' as EMU approached.<br />

The fiscal criteria said budget deficits must not be excessive, interpreted to mean that budget deficits should<br />

be less than 3 per cent of GDP and that the debt/GDP ratio should not be over 60 per cent. Tight fiscal<br />

policy would mean there was little pressure on the central bank to print money to bail out fiscal authorities.<br />

In 2009 Greece admitted that its previous national statistics had been inaccurate and that its budget deficit<br />

was much larger than had previously been reported. This immediately led to speculative pressure against<br />

an EMU member state, precisely what the Maastricht Treaty had sought to avoid.<br />

At the time, many economists complained that the Maastricht criteria were caution taken to extremes. An<br />

independent central bank with a tough constitution was an adequate commitment to low inflation. It was<br />

unnecessary to constrain fiscal policy as well. Indeed, since national governments would no longer have a<br />

national interest rate or national exchange rate policy to deal with purely national circumstances, leaving<br />

them fiscal room for manoeuvre might be a good idea.<br />

The Maastricht deal reflected the balance of power in the negotiations. At the time, Germany ran the EMS<br />

and trusted itself to do so in its own interests. Why would Germany give up such a good position? Only if<br />

EMU was going to be super-safe. The Maastricht criteria were the price of getting Germany on board.<br />

Sterling and UK membership<br />

Why was the UK reluctant to join both the ERM and EMU? First, until the late 1980s, North Sea oil made<br />

sterling behave differently from other European currencies. As UK oil production slowed down, this<br />

objection evaporated.<br />

Second, whereas the core countries of Europe are now very integrated with one another, offshore UK is less<br />

integrated with the rest of Europe. A common policy may be less suitable. Table 29 .5 shows the composition of<br />

UK trade and how it has changed since the UK joined the EU in 1973. The trend is clear. The UK is becoming<br />

more integrated with continental Europe all the time, even if from a lower baseline than some other European<br />

countries. If this trend continues, the issue is eventually not whether the UK should join but when.<br />

Third, the UK has greater macroeconomic sovereignty: it seems to have more to lose. Whereas ERM<br />

countries had already allowed the 'single' interest rate to be set by Germany alone, sterling floated during<br />

the entire period except for the two years of its ERM membership during 1990-92.<br />

However, the absence of capital controls and the power of the speculators limit monetary sovereignty<br />

whatever the exchange rate regime. The Bank of England has often wished to raise interest rates for<br />

domestic reasons, to cool down a housing boom, but been unprepared to do so because higher interest<br />

rates would bid up further the value of the floating<br />

pound, exacerbating the woes of UK exporters. The<br />

Bank has often found itself hoping for interest rate Table 29.S UK trade patterns (0/o)<br />

rises in Frankfurt and Washington that would allow<br />

EU North America<br />

it to raise sterling interest rates without causing a<br />

further appreciation of sterling. 1970<br />

Finally, Black Wednesday (16 September 1992)<br />

made it hard for UK politicians to enthuse about<br />

EMU. While Chancellor, John Major took the UK<br />

into the ERM in 1990 to combat rising inflation at<br />

2005<br />

34<br />

17<br />

62 1 1<br />

Rest of world<br />

Sources: UN, /nternationol Trade Statistics; www.statistics.gov.uk.<br />

49<br />

27<br />

673

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!