07.09.2017 Views

David K.H. Begg, Gianluigi Vernasca-Economics-McGraw Hill Higher Education (2011)

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

CHAPTER 21 Aggregate supply, prices and adjustment to shocks<br />

A temporary supply shock<br />

shifts the short-run aggregate<br />

supply schedule, but leaves<br />

potential output unaltered.<br />

Monetary policy<br />

accommodates a<br />

temporary supply shock<br />

when monetary policy is<br />

altered to help stabilize output.<br />

The consequence, however, is<br />

higher inflation.<br />

c<br />

0<br />

;<br />

0<br />

;:<br />

c<br />

-<br />

A temporary supply shock<br />

A temporary supply shock leaves potential output unaffected in the long run.<br />

With the vertical AS schedule unaltered, the short-run supply curve must shift.<br />

Although the SAS schedule is mainly influenced by inherited nominal wages, it is<br />

also affected by other input prices. Suppose a temporary oil price rise makes firms<br />

charge higher prices at any output level. Figure 21.10 shows a shift upwards in<br />

short-run supply, from SAS to SAS'. The new short-run equilibrium is at E'.<br />

Inflation rises but output and employment fall because the central bank raises real<br />

interest rates in response to higher inflation.<br />

If the central bank maintains its inflation target n*, lower output and employment<br />

at E' gradually reduce inflation and nominal wage growth, shifting SAS' gradually back to SAS. The<br />

economy slowly moves down the AD schedule back to the original equilibrium at E.<br />

A different outcome is possible. When the higher oil price shifts SAS to SAS', it is possible to avoid the<br />

period oflow output as the economy moves along AD from E' back to E. A change in monetary policy can<br />

shift AD up enough to pass through E'. Output can quickly return to potential output, but only because the<br />

inflation target 4 has been loosened from n* to n*". The new long-run new equilibrium is then at E".<br />

A central bank caring a lot about output stability may accommodate short-run supply shocks, even if this<br />

means higher inflation. A central bank caring more about its inflation target than about output stability<br />

will not accommodate temporary supply shocks.<br />

n*"<br />

rt'<br />

n * Y' y<br />

Output<br />

<strong>Higher</strong> oil prices force firms to raise prices. In the short run,<br />

SAS shifts up to SAS', and equilibrium shifts from E to E'.<br />

<strong>Higher</strong> inflation reduces aggregate demand since the central<br />

bank raises real interest rates. Once the temporary supply<br />

shock disappears, SAS' gradually falls back to SAS, and<br />

equilibrium is eventually restored at E.<br />

Figure 21.10 A temporary supply shock<br />

y<br />

It matters a lot whether the supply shock is temporary<br />

or permanent. If potential output is permanently<br />

affected, aggregate demand must eventually rise to<br />

match. Once a supply side shock is diagnosed as<br />

permanent, it should be accommodated.<br />

Demand shocks<br />

Figure 21.11 explores demand shocks not caused by<br />

monetary policy. If demand is high, facing AD' the<br />

economy moves along its short-run supply curve to<br />

point A. If demand is low, facing AD" the economy<br />

moves along the SAS curve to point B.<br />

Suppose the central bank diagnoses that an<br />

expansionary demand shock has occurred. It can<br />

tighten monetary policy and shift AD' back down<br />

to AD again. Similarly, it can loosen monetary<br />

policy in response to low aggregate demand AD",<br />

restoring AD again. The economy remains at E.<br />

Both inflation and output are stabilized.<br />

It is easy for the central bank to tell where inflation<br />

is relative to its target rate. It is harder to estimate<br />

the level of potential output, which can change over<br />

time. This is part of the modern case for using<br />

4 Looser monetary policy shifts the ii schedule to the right in Figure 21.1. However, once long-run equilibrium is restored i* must<br />

be unaltered: since aggregate supply is eventually unaltered, aggregate demand cannot eventually change. The only way for the<br />

central bank to loosen monetary policy without changing i* is to accept a higher inflation target n * .<br />

494

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!