07.09.2017 Views

David K.H. Begg, Gianluigi Vernasca-Economics-McGraw Hill Higher Education (2011)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

3.8 Consumer and producer surplus<br />

Government regulations can sometimes be viewed as<br />

imposing a technological change that is adverse for<br />

producers. If so, the effect of regulations will be to shift<br />

the supply curve to the left, reducing quantity supplied<br />

at each price.<br />

More stringent safety regulations prevent chocolate<br />

producers using the most productive process because<br />

it is quite dangerous to workers. Anti-pollution devices<br />

may raise the cost of making cars, and regulations<br />

to protect the environment may make it unprofitable<br />

for firms to extract surface mineral deposits which<br />

could have been cheaply quarried but whose extraction<br />

now requires expensive landscaping. Whenever<br />

regulations prevent producers from selecting the<br />

production methods they would otherwise have chosen,<br />

the effect of regulations is to shift the supply curve to<br />

the left.<br />

Cl<br />

...<br />

0<br />

0<br />

"'<br />

0<br />

.c<br />

"'<br />

-<br />

0<br />

Cl<br />

"'<br />

'i::<br />

A.<br />

Pi<br />

Po<br />

s<br />

0 01 Oo<br />

Quantity of chocolate<br />

s<br />

D<br />

Shifts in the supply curve<br />

Along a given supply curve, we hold constant technology,<br />

the prices of inputs and the extent of government<br />

regulation. Any change in those factors will shift the<br />

supply curve. We now undertake a comparative static<br />

analysis of what happens when a change in one of these<br />

The supply curve initially is SS and market equilibrium<br />

is at E. A reduction in the supply of chocolate shifts the<br />

supply curve to the left to S'S'. The new equilibrium at E'<br />

has a higher equilibrium price and a lower equilibrium<br />

quantity than the old equilibrium at E.<br />

Figure 3.5 A fall in supply<br />

'other things equal' leads to a fall in supply. Suppose tougher safety legislation makes it more expensive to<br />

make chocolate bars in mechanized factories. Figure 3.5 shows a shift to the left in the supply curve, from<br />

SS to S'S'. Equilibrium shifts from E to E'.<br />

The equilibrium price rises but equilibrium quantity falls when the supply curve shifts to the left. Conversely,<br />

a rise in supply shifts the supply curve from S'S' to SS. Equilibrium shifts from E' to E. A rise in supply<br />

induces a higher equilibrium quantity and lower equilibrium price.<br />

<br />

C_ o _ n _ su _m_ e _ r a_ n _ d _ p _ ro _ d _ u c_ er _ s _ u r _ p _ l u _ s <br />

In previous sections we defined the market equilibrium. Can we say something about how 'good' a market<br />

equilibrium is? In practice, we want to find a possible measure for the gains that consumers and sellers<br />

obtain from trading at the equilibrium price. For the consumers, this measure of trade gain is called<br />

consumer surplus.<br />

For a single consumer, the consumer surplus is the difference between the maximum price (also called the<br />

reservation price) that she is willing to pay for a given amount of a good or service and the price she actually<br />

pays.<br />

Suppose that you want to buy the latest CD of your favourite artist. You are willing to pay a maximum £15<br />

for it. If the price of the CD at the shop is £8, you buy it, and you can say that from buying it you have<br />

obtained a surplus of £7. This surplus is a measure of your gain from buying the CD.<br />

53

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!