07.09.2017 Views

David K.H. Begg, Gianluigi Vernasca-Economics-McGraw Hill Higher Education (2011)

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

8.9 Monopoly and technical change<br />

from previously sold units. Hence the demand curve<br />

is the marginal revenue curve under perfect price<br />

discrimination. The marginal revenue of the last unit<br />

is simply the price for which it is sold.<br />

Treating DD as the marginal revenue curve, a<br />

perfectly price-discriminating monopolist produces<br />

at point C, where marginal revenue and marginal<br />

cost are equal. Two points follow immediately. First,<br />

if price discrimination is possible, it is profitable to<br />

use it. Moving from the uniform pricing point A to<br />

the price discriminating point C, the monopolist adds<br />

the area ABC to profits. This is the excess of extra<br />

revenue over extra cost when output is increased.<br />

The monopolist makes a second gain from price<br />

discrimination. Even the output Q1 now earns more<br />

revenue than under uniform pricing. The monopolist<br />

also gains the area EP1A by charging different prices<br />

on the first Q1 units of output rather than the single<br />

price P1• In practice, one of the main ways management<br />

consultants raise the profits of firms that they<br />

advise is by devising new ways in which the firm can<br />

price discriminate.<br />

Second, whether or not the firm can price discriminate<br />

affects its output choice. Uniform pricing leads to an<br />

output Q1• Perfect price discrimination leads to an<br />

output Q2• Uniform and discriminatory pricing lead<br />

to different outputs because they affect the marginal<br />

revenue obtained by a monopolist from a given<br />

demand curve.<br />

0<br />

MR :<br />

I<br />

I<br />

02<br />

Output<br />

Charging all customers the same price the monopolist will<br />

produce at B where MC = MR. If each output unit can be<br />

sold for a different price the revenue from existing units<br />

is not reduced by cutting the price to sell another unit.<br />

The demand curve DD is the marginal revenue curve<br />

and the perfectly discriminating monopolist will produce<br />

at C. Output is higher and profits are higher. By price<br />

discrimination the monopolist gains an extra revenue EP1A<br />

from selling Q1 but also increases output beyond this level<br />

making a marginal profit of ABC in expanding from Q1 to Q2.<br />

Figure 8.15<br />

Perfect price discrimination<br />

Perfect price discrimination is normally not feasible in reality. In order to perfectly discriminate, the<br />

monopolist should know the willingness to pay of each consumer, information that is impractical to obtain.<br />

Nevertheless, perfect discrimination gives an interesting result. If the monopolist can perfectly discriminate,<br />

the social loss associated with a monopoly disappears. The social surplus under a monopoly that perfectly<br />

discriminates is the same as under perfect competition. However, the distribution of the social surplus is<br />

completely different in the two cases. Under perfect competition the producer surplus is zero, while the<br />

social surplus coincides with the consumers' surplus. For a perfectly discriminating monopolist, the<br />

reverse is true. The perfectly discriminating monopolist extracts the entire consumers' surplus, and so<br />

the social surplus coincides with the producer surplus (the profits of the monopolist).<br />

<br />

M_o_n_op_o_ly_a_n_d_te_ ch _n_i c a_l_ ch _a_ng_e <br />

Section 8. 7 compared a monopoly and a perfectly competitive industry. When such a comparison was<br />

meaningful, we discovered: (1) a monopoly will restrict output and drive up prices, and (2) a monopoly<br />

may make economic profits permanently.<br />

Joseph Schumpeter (1883-1950) argued that this comparison ignores technical advances that reduce costs,<br />

allowing price cuts and output expansion. A large monopolist with steady profits may find it easier to fund<br />

191

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!