07.09.2017 Views

David K.H. Begg, Gianluigi Vernasca-Economics-McGraw Hill Higher Education (2011)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

4.9 Who really pays the tax?<br />

S'<br />

-<br />

GI<br />

u<br />

c<br />

GI<br />

100<br />

GI<br />

u<br />

95<br />

•t:<br />

A.<br />

S'<br />

s<br />

s<br />

-<br />

GI<br />

u<br />

; 105<br />

100<br />

u<br />

GI<br />

•t:<br />

A.<br />

D<br />

55 ------------------<br />

D'<br />

01 Oo<br />

Quantity<br />

(a) Steep demand, flat supply<br />

01 Oo<br />

Quantity<br />

(b) Flat demand, steep supply<br />

Figure 4.7<br />

Tax incidence<br />

Either way, what we want to know is who ends up paying the tax. Suppose for simplicity we imagine a<br />

packet of cigarettes costs £1 and the government imposes a specific tax of SOp per packet. Do smokers end<br />

up paying the tax, or is it borne by cigarette producers? How much of the tax can producers pass on to the<br />

consumer? We now show that this depends on the slopes of the supply and demand curves.<br />

Figures 4.7(a) and 4.7(b) plot the (after-tax) price to the consumer on the vertical axis. DD' shows the<br />

demand curve, which depends on the price to smokers (consumers). Since the price received by the<br />

producer is the consumer price minus the SOp tax per packet, the effect of the tax is to shift the supply<br />

curve from SS to S'S' in both diagrams. Each possible quantity supplied depends on the price received by<br />

the producer, which will be the same as before only if consumer prices are SOp higher: that is why we must<br />

shift the supply curve up by SOp.<br />

In Figure 4.7(a), with a flat supply curve and steep demand curve, the tax is borne mainly by cigarette<br />

consumers. Point B is nearly SOp higher than point A. Since demand is insensitive to price, producers can<br />

pass on most of the tax in higher prices. Supply is price-sensitive, so the price received by producers cannot<br />

fall much. Consumers pay £1.4S and producers get £0.9S a packet.<br />

In Figure 4. 7(b ), with a flat demand curve and a steep supply curve, most of the tax is borne by cigarette<br />

producers. Demand is price-sensitive, so attempts to pass on the tax in higher prices quickly lead to a drop<br />

in sales. Supply is price-insensitive and producers hardly cut back even though the price they receive has<br />

fallen nearly sop. Consumers pay £1.0S and producers get £0.SS a packet.<br />

The key implication is thus that the incidence of a tax - who eventually bears the<br />

burden - has nothing to do with who initially hands over money to the government.<br />

The existence of the tax changes behaviour. This has induced effects on equilibrium<br />

price and quantity. These induced effects may be large or small, depending on the<br />

slopes of supply and demand curves.<br />

The incidence of a tax<br />

describes who eventually bears<br />

the burden of that tax.<br />

Now that we understand the general principle, it is obvious that the same argument will carry over to the<br />

more commonly used ad valorem taxes. We simply need to remember to confront the change in the<br />

percentage tax rate with the relevant percentage measures of price responsiveness of supply and demand,<br />

namely the (own-price) supply and demand elasticities.<br />

85

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!