07.09.2017 Views

David K.H. Begg, Gianluigi Vernasca-Economics-McGraw Hill Higher Education (2011)

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

CHAPTER 28 International trade<br />

Conversely, the UK has the largest comparative advantage in making shoes, the good in which UK<br />

producers are most efficient relative to US producers. As we move to the left, the comparative advantage of<br />

the UK declines; US producers become increasingly efficient relative to UK producers.<br />

The US has an absolute advantage in producing computers, cars, TVs and textiles. The UK has an absolute<br />

advantage in producing glass and shoes. Nevertheless, absolute advantage plays no direct part in the<br />

analysis. Comparative advantage is what counts.<br />

The equilibrium exchange rate occurs at some intermediate level that just balances the value of trade<br />

between the two countries. Essentially, the level of the exchange rate takes care of the overall level of<br />

absolute advantage, leaving comparative advantage to determine trade patterns.<br />

Different capital-labour ratios<br />

Comparative advantage need not depend on technology differences. It may also reflect different factor<br />

supplies. Consider the UK and China. The UK has more capital per worker than China. Even though<br />

China's vast size may mean that it has absolutely more capital than the UK, the UK has relatively more<br />

capital than China.<br />

What does this imply about the relative price of hiring labour and capital in the two countries? With more<br />

capital per worker, the marginal product oflabour is higher in the UK. This makes real wages higher in the<br />

UK than in China. Conversely, the number of workers per unit of capital is lower in the UK than in China.<br />

The marginal product of capital and the rental of capital will tend to be lower in the UK, where machinery<br />

is relatively plentiful, than in China, where machinery is relatively scarce. Because the UK is endowed with<br />

more capital relative to labour than China, the cost of using labour relative to capital is higher in the UK<br />

than in China.<br />

Relative costs of using inputs affect the relative price of the goods they produce. Goods made by labourintensive<br />

methods cost relatively more to make in the UK than in China. Suppose car production is capital<br />

intensive with sophisticated assembly lines, but textile production is labour intensive with detailed tasks<br />

best done by hand. The price of cars relative to textiles is lower in the UK than in China.<br />

Hence, a relatively abundant supply or endowment of one factor of production tends to make the cost of<br />

renting that factor relatively cheap. Goods that use that factor relatively intensively are thus relatively<br />

cheap. In these goods the country has a comparative advantage. Thus the UK, relatively generously supplied<br />

with capital relative to labour, exports capital-intensive cars to China. China, relatively well endowed with<br />

labour, should export labour-intensive textiles to the UK. Differences in relative factor supply are an<br />

important explanation for comparative advantage and the pattern of international trade.<br />

Figure 28.1 supports this analysis. It emphasizes skills, or human capital, rather than physical capital,<br />

although the two are usually correlated. Countries with scarce land but abundant skills have high shares of<br />

manufactures in their exports. Countries with lots ofland but few skills typically export raw materials. The<br />

figure also shows regional averages. Africa lies at one end, the industrial countries at the other.<br />

We now have two explanations for comparative advantage or international differences in relative production<br />

costs. The first is the Ricardian explanation - international differences in technology that cause differences<br />

in relative physical productivity and relative unit labour requirements. Second, even if countries have<br />

access to the same technology, the domestic relative price of goods may differ across countries because the<br />

relative cost of renting factor inputs differs across countries. Where a factor is in relatively abundant supply,<br />

goods that use that factor relatively intensively are likely to be relatively cheaper than in other countries. 3<br />

3 Strictly speaking, this explains differences in relative prices before countries start trading. Export demand may bid up the<br />

relative price of the good until relative prices are equalized across countries. This explains why trade is not infinite. Nevertheless,<br />

beginning from no trade, comparative advantage explains which goods the country then exports and which it imports.<br />

642

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!