05.06.2013 Views

Recasting Citizenship for Development - File UPI

Recasting Citizenship for Development - File UPI

Recasting Citizenship for Development - File UPI

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Women and Water Policy 247<br />

advances in this direction. The driving <strong>for</strong>ce behind this thinking was a<br />

strong production agenda. Improved irrigation facilities, along with other<br />

agricultural inputs, have had a phenomenal impact on the overall development<br />

in agriculture. However, the many benefits are also accompanied<br />

by water insecurity <strong>for</strong> a large number of poor women and men. Expansion<br />

of irrigation to meet the livelihood requirements of the poor has<br />

rarely been on the irrigation agenda.<br />

The present policy thrust is focused on the pricing of water, recovery<br />

of capital costs, and decentralised management of the resource. In the following<br />

section we look at the impact this has on water-deprived groups,<br />

particularly women (see Kulkarni 2005).<br />

PRICING AND COST RECOVERY<br />

With the policy thrust on treating water as an economic good, debates<br />

around water pricing and full cost recovery are now gaining ground. The<br />

irrigation sector has been recognised as a loss-making one, and the state<br />

there<strong>for</strong>e wants to rid itself of the responsibility of managing it. One of<br />

the solutions to recovering the costs of operation and management is seen<br />

in the user pays principle. Although fine in theory as far as the productive<br />

use of water is concerned, in plain terms it simply implies that only those<br />

who are ready, willing and have the ability to pay will have access to water.<br />

No distinction is made in pricing policies <strong>for</strong> water <strong>for</strong> livelihood needs<br />

and water requirements beyond that.<br />

This has two kinds of implications: the first is the priority given to<br />

industrial water use over irrigation <strong>for</strong> agriculture. Since the simple rule<br />

of economics says that allocation is to be accorded to wherever the returns<br />

are the highest, water <strong>for</strong> industry becomes the more favoured option.<br />

The second implication is vis-à-vis cropping preferences within irrigated<br />

areas. As men increasingly come to see greater advantages in either selling<br />

or using the available water to generate cash incomes, there is the possibility<br />

that access to water <strong>for</strong> non-marketable produce or survival tasks<br />

will be restricted (Green and Baden 1995). In such a scenario, it is usually<br />

the ‘paying’ crops that get preference over the ‘non-paying’ food crops<br />

largely cultivated by women. Women have often in<strong>for</strong>mally used irrigation<br />

water <strong>for</strong> micro-enterprises concerning small-scale activities, such as goat

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!