15.01.2013 Views

CAPITALISM'S ACHILLES HEEL Dirty Money and How to

CAPITALISM'S ACHILLES HEEL Dirty Money and How to

CAPITALISM'S ACHILLES HEEL Dirty Money and How to

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Philosophy Becomes Culture 315<br />

introvert, <strong>and</strong> not a particularly keen observer of society. He wrote widely<br />

on science, meteorology, music, gold, coal, trade, currency, taxes, trade<br />

unions, <strong>and</strong> married women in fac<strong>to</strong>ries. He embarrassed himself attempting<br />

<strong>to</strong> relate sun spots <strong>to</strong> agricultural cycles. But he never w<strong>and</strong>ered far from<br />

his utilitarian foundations, placing objective utility above all other considerations:<br />

“[T]hrow aside all supposed absolute rights or inflexible principles.” 5<br />

“The liberty of the subject is only the means <strong>to</strong>wards an end; it is not itself<br />

the end; hence, when it fails <strong>to</strong> produce the desired end, it may be set aside,<br />

<strong>and</strong> other means employed.” 6 “I conceive that the State is justified in passing<br />

any law, or even in doing any single act which, without ulterior consequences,<br />

adds <strong>to</strong> the sum <strong>to</strong>tal of happiness.” 7 Thus, rights, inflexible principles,<br />

liberty, justice, all can be subjugated if they do not produce desired<br />

ends. “We must hold <strong>to</strong> the dry old Jeremy, if we are <strong>to</strong> have any chance of<br />

progress in Ethics.” 8<br />

Jevons fixed utility at the forefront of economics <strong>and</strong> opened the door<br />

for mathematics <strong>to</strong> be the principal <strong>to</strong>ol of analysis. He largely initiated the<br />

shift from political economy <strong>to</strong> pure economy. At the same time another<br />

shift was occurring, <strong>to</strong> Cambridge University, which came <strong>to</strong> dominate economic<br />

study for nearly 75 years.<br />

A leading luminary at Cambridge was Henry Sidgwick, who was perhaps<br />

the last of nineteenth century thinkers able <strong>to</strong> converse with equal authority<br />

on both ethics <strong>and</strong> economics. He published The Methods of Ethics in<br />

1874 <strong>and</strong> Principles of Political Economy in 1883, <strong>and</strong> then returned again <strong>to</strong><br />

philosophy with Practical Ethics in 1898.<br />

Sidgwick attempted <strong>to</strong> prove that utilitarianism’s fundamental precept<br />

of the “greatest happiness for the greatest number” was superior <strong>to</strong> other<br />

philosophical hypotheses focused more inwardly. He referred <strong>to</strong> these two<br />

governing motivations as “duty” <strong>and</strong> “interests,” constituting the “dualism<br />

of practical reason.” Alas, he was unable <strong>to</strong> make an irrefutable case for the<br />

former, lamenting that “Utilitarian Duty . . . cannot be satisfac<strong>to</strong>rily<br />

demonstrated on empirical grounds.” 9 As he sadly concluded, “[T]he prolonged<br />

effort of the human intellect <strong>to</strong> frame a perfect ideal of rational conduct<br />

is seen <strong>to</strong> have been foredoomed <strong>to</strong> inevitable failure.” 10<br />

This did not prevent Sidgwick from retaining utilitarianism at the center<br />

of his convictions. Attempting <strong>to</strong> apply his attachment <strong>to</strong> the greatest<br />

good, he tried <strong>to</strong> argue for more equal income distribution <strong>and</strong> against unbridled<br />

laissez-faire. But Sidgwick’s innate conservatism <strong>and</strong> preference for

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!