25.09.2015 Views

Changing public space

Changing public space

Changing public space

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

increase in the number of rules or cameras in the area (Cybriwsky, 1999; Kohn, 2004; Low, 2005).<br />

The second possible effect, therefore, is that the private-sector involvement leads to restricted<br />

access of <strong>public</strong> <strong>space</strong>. The two effects are elaborated below. Section 4.4.3 briefly discusses how<br />

private-sector involvement could also affect redeveloped <strong>public</strong> <strong>space</strong> in other ways.<br />

4.4.1 Budget<br />

Private-sector involvement in urban redevelopment might make more funds available to upgrade<br />

<strong>public</strong> <strong>space</strong>. Local governments tended to give low priority to the design and management of<br />

<strong>public</strong> <strong>space</strong>, as other responsibilities took precedence such as sanitation and road maintenance<br />

(Carr et al., 1992). In many cases, the capacity to provide continuous upkeep and maintenance<br />

has always been limited and is further decreasing as a result of caps on <strong>public</strong> budgets. However,<br />

local governments currently face a growing competition to attract the increasingly mobile<br />

higher-income residents, tourists, investments, and businesses. They realise that it is not sufficient<br />

to only have a number of impressive buildings and events in the city, but that <strong>public</strong> <strong>space</strong>s of<br />

good quality can also lend a positive image to the city and its lifestyle. To find the appropriate<br />

budget to redevelop <strong>public</strong> <strong>space</strong>, local governments need to turn to the private sector, which – in<br />

contrast to the <strong>public</strong> sector – can usually raise the required investments.<br />

As described above, investors such as pension funds, life assurance companies, and large stock<br />

market listed property companies have become increasingly aware that it can be in their own<br />

interest to invest in the quality of <strong>public</strong> <strong>space</strong> to enhance the market appeal and long-term rental<br />

potential of their property (Blank, 2007). A clear example of this positive return on investment<br />

is the 1961 incentive zoning policy that was enacted in New York City. Here, developers were<br />

stimulated to create ‘privately owned <strong>public</strong> <strong>space</strong>s’ (POPS) in or on their property in exchange<br />

for extra floor surface (Kayden, 2000; Smithsimon, 2008). This had positive effects for both the<br />

<strong>public</strong> and the developers: over 500 new POPS were created between 1961 and 2000, which led<br />

to an increase in the rental potential of the property. A policy instrument similar to incentive<br />

zoning does not exist in the Netherlands, but the idea that <strong>public</strong> <strong>space</strong> increases the property<br />

value has become common and has acted as incentive for the private sector to invest in <strong>public</strong><br />

<strong>space</strong>.<br />

The financial contribution by the private sector can range from direct and semi-direct to<br />

indirect investments. In the first option, private parties buy land from the local government and<br />

finance the development and management of both buildings and <strong>public</strong> <strong>space</strong>. Sometimes the<br />

land is sold to the private sector for a nominal sum, because it is also held responsible to invest<br />

in the outdoor <strong>space</strong>. This direct financial contribution mostly occurs in the development of new<br />

neighbourhoods at the city’s edge, but can also take place in the city centre. The investment of<br />

the private sector can also be semi-direct. In this case, the local government redevelops <strong>public</strong><br />

<strong>space</strong>, but the private parties – usually owners of property abutting the redeveloped <strong>public</strong><br />

<strong>space</strong> – provide extra investments to boost the municipal budget. This could be voluntary<br />

as well as compulsory through special assessments. In the Netherlands, this is known as<br />

baatbelasting (Overwater, 2002). This implies that local entrepreneurs are forced to pay a certain<br />

contribution (depending on the function and size of their property), because they supposedly<br />

profit from the improvements in <strong>public</strong> <strong>space</strong>. The contribution is limited to the redevelopment<br />

costs; the management costs cannot be recouped (Needham, 2007). The third mode of<br />

financial contribution of the private sector refers to situations in which the local government<br />

redevelops <strong>public</strong> <strong>space</strong> with the yields raised through the sale of the land, in Dutch known as<br />

77

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!