25.09.2015 Views

Changing public space

Changing public space

Changing public space

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

grondexploitatie (Wigmans, 2002). In this case, the private sector buys part of the <strong>public</strong> <strong>space</strong><br />

from the local government in order to develop a new building. The municipality subsequently<br />

uses this yield to finance the redevelopment of the remaining <strong>public</strong> <strong>space</strong>. Profits are thus<br />

reinvested in the project in order to increase its quality. This approach, in which the private sector<br />

contributes indirectly, is also known as value capturing (Priemus, 2005).<br />

4.4.2 Free access<br />

However, companies are not in business to solve <strong>public</strong> problems such as unattractive <strong>public</strong><br />

<strong>space</strong>s. The only way the private sector can realise a good return on investment is by concentrating<br />

on the bottom line. As Staeheli and Mitchell (2006) have discovered in their research, the<br />

function as a <strong>public</strong> gathering-place is clearly secondary in privately owned areas like shopping<br />

malls. The primary function of these <strong>space</strong>s is to generate income, which is often obtained by<br />

increasing the control at the expense of accessibility, also known as the security-profitability nexus<br />

(Cybriwsky, 1999; Staeheli & Mitchell, 2006). According to Carr et al. (1992: 363), “… there is<br />

typically a perceived conflict between the developer’s interest in bottom-line profitability and<br />

the <strong>public</strong>ness of <strong>public</strong> <strong>space</strong> …”. This was also the conclusion of the inventory of all POPS in<br />

New York. Although the zoning policy seemed successful with the addition of 500 new POPS, it<br />

appeared that a large number of these <strong>space</strong>s were either of marginal quality or did not conform<br />

to the zoning requirements. Some were closed during specified opening hours; others did not<br />

provide the promised amenities or posed strict entry restrictions (Kayden, 2000; Smithsimon,<br />

2008). Meyer et al. (2006) also warn that such private <strong>space</strong>s will only temporarily be <strong>public</strong>ly<br />

accessible. They base their argument on the famous 1748 Nolli map of Rome, in which squares,<br />

streets, and other <strong>public</strong> <strong>space</strong> (i.e., formal <strong>space</strong>) is indicated in white, and privately owned but<br />

<strong>public</strong>ly accessible <strong>space</strong> such as churches (i.e., informal <strong>space</strong>) in grey. When comparing the<br />

map to the current situation, it appears that most formal <strong>public</strong> <strong>space</strong> is still <strong>public</strong>, while most<br />

informal <strong>space</strong> is not (Meyer et al., 2006).<br />

The involvement of the private sector might thus create <strong>public</strong> <strong>space</strong>s that are less widely<br />

accessible than <strong>public</strong> <strong>space</strong>s developed and managed solely by the local government. MacLeod<br />

(2002), for example, has associated the entrepreneurial city with the so-called ‘revanchist city’, a<br />

term coined by Neil Smith (1996). He argues that the two go hand-in-hand: because of private<br />

investment and the focus on consumerist citizenship in the entrepreneurial city, vulnerable<br />

groups such as homeless people are being disregarded and chased away. Although the revanchistcity<br />

framework is very much derived from developments in New York (Smith, 1996; DeFilippis,<br />

2004), MacLeod believes it is an important heuristic tool to also describe changes in the urban<br />

landscape elsewhere. Several other commentators have also drawn attention to the exclusionary<br />

effects associated with the regulation of <strong>public</strong> <strong>space</strong>. Some call it the ‘end of <strong>public</strong> <strong>space</strong>’<br />

(Sorkin, 1992; Kohn, 2004); others identify a transformation of <strong>public</strong> <strong>space</strong> from open access<br />

toward heightened control over access (Carr et al., 1992; Mitchell, 1995; DeFilippis, 1997). The<br />

discussion can be placed within a wider debate on the increasing division of today’s post-Fordist<br />

city and its exclusionary effects on some groups of people. Marcuse (1995) has defined this as<br />

the quartered city, in which enclaves of wealth and power (‘the dominating city’) coexist with the<br />

socially excluded (‘the abandoned city’) and other types of residential and economic ‘cities’ within<br />

the city. Others have elaborated on this notion of a divided city and have introduced terms as<br />

the fortress city (Davis, 1992), splintering urbanism (Graham & Marvin, 2001), and archipelago of<br />

enclaves (Hajer & Reijndorp, 2001). The terms indicate a widespread erosion of <strong>public</strong> sympathy<br />

78

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!