25.07.2013 Views

Um Novo Modelo para o Setor Elétrico Brasileiro

Um Novo Modelo para o Setor Elétrico Brasileiro

Um Novo Modelo para o Setor Elétrico Brasileiro

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Especificamente sobre o Brasil, o autor comenta 12 acima :<br />

“Brazil, like California, faces an electricity crisis, and like California,<br />

raises awkward questions and points to the cost of flawed and<br />

inappropriate reforms. (…) The reforms, started in 1990, were given<br />

more momentum by the Cardoso administration from 1994, and were<br />

heavily influenced by the English model of unbundling, competition<br />

and privatisation (with the possible exception of transmission).<br />

The distinctive feature of Brazil that contrasts sharply with Britain is<br />

that it is dominantly (95%) hydro-based with large multi-year storage<br />

dams, and relatively recent access to gas, with an immature gas<br />

network and market. In contrast to almost all other countries, the<br />

long-run marginal cost of additional hydro investment is probably<br />

lower than that of CCGT. In addition, dispatching the dams gains<br />

considerably from basinwide coordination (allowing perhaps an<br />

additional 20% firm power), while considerable rainfall fluctuations<br />

mean that it is advisable to maintain adequate water reserves, or<br />

face, as at present, severe and long-duration shortages when rains<br />

fail and dams have been depleted. Finally, the dams are multi-use,<br />

and managing them for irrigation and other water uses requires close<br />

coordination between the water management authorities and power<br />

dispatch.<br />

These conditions are the least propitious for a competitive, privately<br />

owned generation market. Investing in multi-use hydro-electric<br />

projects that need coordinated regulation creates considerable private<br />

investor risk. Dams are entirely front-end loaded, with negligible<br />

running costs but massive investment costs. The gains from private<br />

operation (once built) are thus likely to be small, and the risks that<br />

prices will be held down in periods of tight demand high, while if<br />

water is spilled, prices may fall almost to zero in a competitive<br />

market. Investing in CCGT is equally unattractive, for although from a<br />

least-cost system expansion view point, some low capital cost flexible<br />

plant may be desirable, the financial economics look terrible. It would<br />

only operate in drought years, and the overall load factor would<br />

probably be less than 35%. Its average cost would exceed the LRMC<br />

of hydro, and if hydro prices are suppressed in periods of shortage,<br />

then the average price will be even lower, and hence unremunerative<br />

without special payments for its role as emergency capacity or<br />

reserve.<br />

The uncomfortable conclusion is that it is unlikely that private<br />

ownership of generation is an efficient way to plan, develop and<br />

finance the generation sector in Brazil. It is an open question whether<br />

it would ever be in countries requiring large-scale multi-use river<br />

basis management schemes. The most favourable circumstances<br />

would be for dams whose sole use is for hydro-electricity, and where<br />

the price of electricity is set by thermal plant, as in Chile and<br />

Argentina. Private involvement in generation has a com<strong>para</strong>tive<br />

advantage where timely construction and maintenance are required<br />

to deliver possible efficiency benefits, but is least likely to work in<br />

dominantly hydro systems.<br />

19

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!