21.01.2014 Views

Solar Energy Perspectives - IEA

Solar Energy Perspectives - IEA

Solar Energy Perspectives - IEA

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Chapter 10: Policies<br />

fossil-fuel plants are not needed to meet demand, so these plants no longer set the<br />

electricity price. The market price at such times drop to the much lower costs of renewable<br />

generators, as has already being seen in the German and Spanish electricity markets with<br />

large penetration of wind power. One immediate effect is that wholesale electricity prices<br />

are reduced, to the benefit of deregulated customers. Unfortunately, this effect – one of<br />

several so-called “merit-order effects” – is hardly noticeable on customer bills. It is hidden<br />

by other cost variation factors, while an “add-on” to the price of electricity is usually made<br />

very explicit and understood as a pure subsidy for renewables, which it is only in<br />

(declining) part. Longer-term effects are considered below.<br />

In deregulated markets, a large share of renewables very often leads to low wholesale<br />

electricity spot prices. While higher peak prices (and associated infra-marginal rents) could<br />

theoretically compensate, this would be a highly uncertain and volatile revenue stream,<br />

making investments for new generating capacities riskier and more difficult to finance. This<br />

could affect both additional renewable capacities, and fossil-fuelled plants required to<br />

serve as balancing plants. <strong>Solar</strong> electricity generating capacities, even offering competitive<br />

prices, may not develop further in electricity spot markets based on marginal pricing, i.e.<br />

driven by marginal running costs. Offers are confronted every minute, while investors in<br />

solar capacities require visibility of income for 15 or 20 years.<br />

The conventional wisdom is that when renewables reach competitiveness, support systems<br />

must be dismantled. While support schemes should certainly not convey a permanent<br />

“subsidy”, it is yet unclear how electricity markets should be designed to support<br />

continuous deployment of renewables. This question is relevant not only for the long term,<br />

when shares of renewables in electricity generation are expected to reach very high levels,<br />

but already today for wind, and in the next few years for solar energy in the many<br />

competitive situations that are emerging.<br />

Several governments have begun to publish proposals to address this factor. The UK<br />

government, which foresees low capacity margins in its electric system by 2018, proposed<br />

in December 2010 to introduce a capacity mechanism to contract for avoiding shortages.<br />

This would involve payments to generators for maintaining contracted amounts of surplus<br />

availability to supply the market. Such an approach is more likely to keep fossil-fuelled<br />

plants in operation even with unprofitably low capacity factors, rather than to extend the<br />

development of renewable capacities.<br />

The current UK proposal for renewable electricity, called “contracts for difference FIT”, looks<br />

like an adjustable FIP similar in principle to the FIP for CSP in Spain. This is a proven<br />

solution for the short term but leaves open the longer-term issues.<br />

Effective, long-term market design for renewable electricity markets is yet to be<br />

conceived. As solar energy technologies come closer to becoming competitive, it is<br />

important that governments do not prematurely dismantle effective and cost-effective<br />

incentive schemes before they set up equally effective and cost-effective electricity<br />

markets, able to reward continuous investments in new renewable capacities and<br />

enabling technologies (grid upgrades, demand-side management, interconnections,<br />

storage and balancing capacities).<br />

189<br />

© OECD/<strong>IEA</strong>, 2011

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!