15.11.2014 Views

capitalism

capitalism

capitalism

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Classical Economics 71<br />

attorney in New York and Los Angeles, opposed the Vietnam<br />

War while remaining a Republican, but when President<br />

Richard Nixon imposed wage and price controls in 1972, he<br />

joined the Libertarian Party and quickly became a member of<br />

its national committee and California State Chair. In 1978, he<br />

stood as the Libertarian candidate for governor of California,<br />

winning 377,960 votes, or about 5.5% of the total cast. That<br />

success led to his selection as the party’s 1980 presidential<br />

nominee. Along with running mate David Koch, a businessman<br />

who made large contributions to the campaign, he<br />

appeared on all 50 state ballots and that of the District of<br />

Columbia, an unprecedented achievement for a third-party<br />

campaign. A close election between Jimmy Carter and<br />

Ronald Reagan and the presence on the ballot of independent<br />

John Anderson may have depressed the party’s chances, and<br />

Clark received 920,000 votes (about 1.1%). Although the<br />

campaign was successful in some ways—it had gained<br />

respectful, if not plentiful, media attention, inspired some<br />

300 Students for Clark organizations, distributed hundreds of<br />

thousands of copies of its campaign book, and placed no less<br />

than 47 five-minute ads on national television—the results<br />

were disappointing. Following the 1980 campaign, many of<br />

Clark’s key supporters appear to have lost interest in the<br />

party, and a number of them drifted away. Clark remains an<br />

active Libertarian, and his wife, Alicia, served as national<br />

chairman from 1981 to 1983.<br />

See also Conscription; MacBride, Roger Lea; Peace and Pacifism;<br />

Price Controls<br />

Further Readings<br />

Clark, Ed. A New Beginning. Ottawa, IL: Caroline House, 1980.<br />

Doherty, Brian. Radicals for Capitalism: A Freewheeling History<br />

of the Modern Libertarian Movement. New York: Public<br />

Affairs, 2007.<br />

Kelley, John L. Bringing the Market Back in: The Political<br />

Revitalization of Market Liberalism. New York: New York<br />

University Press, 1997.<br />

CLASSICAL ECONOMICS<br />

DB<br />

Classical economics refers to a school of economics, the<br />

most famous proponents of which were Adam Smith, Jean-<br />

Baptiste Say, David Ricardo, and John Stuart Mill. Writing<br />

from the end of the 18th to the middle of the 19th centuries,<br />

they shared an approach to economic questions that<br />

embraced market-oriented principles that were to revolutionize<br />

and transform Western civilization. The classical model<br />

of free trade, limited government, balanced budgets, the<br />

gold standard, and laissez-faire shaped orthodox economic<br />

thinking and was accepted by all nonsocialist economists<br />

until the Keynesian revolution of the 1930s. Today, the economic<br />

model put forward by these thinkers is again gaining<br />

popularity.<br />

Adam Smith (1723–1790), one of the most important<br />

figures of the Scottish Enlightenment, is considered the<br />

founder of the classical model. He dubbed it “the system<br />

of natural liberty” in his magnum opus, The Wealth of<br />

Nations. Published in 1776, The Wealth of Nations was a<br />

declaration of economic independence against the prevailing<br />

doctrines of protectionism and state interventionism.<br />

Little progress had been achieved over the centuries<br />

because of the entrenched system known as mercantilism.<br />

The commercial and political powers believed that one<br />

nation gained only at the expense of another and therefore<br />

favored government-authorized monopolies at home and<br />

supported colonialism abroad, sending agents and soldiers<br />

into poorer countries to seize gold and other precious commodities.<br />

Smith carefully delineated the host of high tariffs,<br />

duties, quotas, and regulations that aimed at restraining<br />

imports, production, and employment.<br />

Smith denounced high tariffs and other trade restraints<br />

as counterproductive. Trade barriers hurt the ability of both<br />

countries to produce, he maintained. For example, by<br />

expanding trade between Britain and France, traditional<br />

enemies, both nations would gain: “If a foreign country can<br />

supply us with a commodity cheaper than we ourselves can<br />

make it, better buy it of them.” Smith’s solution to the economic<br />

nationalism and isolationism that then prevailed was<br />

regarded as particularly controversial. It involved the free<br />

movement of labor, capital, money, and goods. Milton<br />

Friedman has noted that “Adam Smith was a radical and a<br />

revolutionary in his time—just as those of us who preach<br />

laissez faire are in our time.” Critics contended that Smith’s<br />

radical suggestions would lead to economic disaster and<br />

instability. To the contrary, Smith promised that the dismantling<br />

of the state regulation of trade, prices, and<br />

employment would lead to “universal opulence which<br />

extends itself to the lowest ranks of the people.”<br />

His eloquent advocacy of natural liberty fired the minds<br />

of a rising generation. The Wealth of Nations literally<br />

changed the course of politics, dismantling the old mercantilist<br />

doctrines of protectionism and poverty. This revolution<br />

in economic policy was a fitting companion to the<br />

American Revolution of 1776 and accelerated the industrialization<br />

of Britain, then in its infancy.<br />

The invisible hand, a term first used by Smith, best<br />

exemplifies his model of economic freedom. In The Wealth<br />

of Nations, Smith argued that if individuals were left to<br />

their own devices, pursuing their own self-interests, they<br />

would generate a self-regulating and highly prosperous<br />

society. George Stigler calls Smith’s invisible-hand doctrine<br />

the “crown jewel” of economics. “Smith had one<br />

overwhelmingly important triumph,” Stigler continued.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!