15.11.2014 Views

capitalism

capitalism

capitalism

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Competition 85<br />

efforts between sellers to cooperate in setting prices above<br />

competitive levels would invariably end in failure. This<br />

argument is consistent with Smith’s view that monopolies<br />

were nothing more than government-granted privileges.<br />

During the early 20th century, the concept of perfect<br />

competition was put forward by economists; it referred to<br />

competition as it would exist under the following five conditions:<br />

first, that there were a large number of buyers and<br />

sellers trading a uniform product; second, that the market<br />

had free entry and exit; third, that all market participants<br />

were fully informed regarding all opportunities for trade;<br />

fourth, that bargaining and price changes cost nothing; and<br />

fifth, that enforcing the terms of a transaction is costless.<br />

Under these conditions, individuals will engage in trades<br />

that bring about perfection in the allocation of existing<br />

resources. This static view of competition treats it as an end<br />

state or goal, rather than an ongoing process.<br />

Some economists have used the theoretical results of<br />

perfect competition as a standard in judging the performance<br />

of real-world markets and found the market system<br />

lacking. In this view, private businesses wield “market<br />

power” to set prices above perfectly competitive levels.<br />

These economists argued that governments could improve<br />

upon actual competition with policies that bring about perfectly<br />

competitive results.<br />

Harold Demsetz has countered these conclusions by<br />

arguing that perfect competition is too high a standard for<br />

either real-world markets or the government to meet. This<br />

argument is true because there is a positive cost to operating<br />

any economic system. Because both competitive<br />

market systems and planned economies cost something to<br />

operate, neither will allocate resources perfectly. These<br />

operating costs create imperfections in both private markets<br />

and the public sector. Demsetz maintained that economists<br />

who condemn the free market on these grounds fail to<br />

account for the possibility that government intervention<br />

aimed toward correcting market imperfections is imperfect.<br />

Thus, when the government intervenes to correct the market,<br />

there always exists the possibility that it might make<br />

matters worse. Demsetz further demonstrated that abnormally<br />

high profit rates tend to disappear over time, thus<br />

negating the purposes of government intervention.<br />

Similarly, Friedrich Hayek argued that the concept of perfect<br />

competition misconstrues the true nature of competition.<br />

According to Hayek, perfect competition represents a<br />

situation where actual competition has ended. To Hayek,<br />

competition is a procedure in which competitors search for<br />

opportunities for profit. Competitors begin this procedure<br />

with relatively little knowledge of the situations that they<br />

face in the markets in which they sell. Competition between<br />

sellers then amounts to a discovery procedure as sellers learn<br />

how to increase their profits and buyers discover new opportunities<br />

for consumption. This analysis directly contradicts<br />

the assumptions of perfect competition, which are predicated<br />

on the presence of perfect information. Hayek stressed that<br />

competition is important precisely because it drives individuals<br />

to improve on the limited knowledge that they possess.<br />

Consequently, attempts to condemn the market system<br />

because sellers lack perfect information make no sense.<br />

Because competition involves the discovery of new<br />

opportunities for trade, the assumption of perfect information<br />

means that “perfect competition” would exist only<br />

in situations where all competition is over. Israel Kirzner<br />

extended Hayek’s arguments in noting the crucial importance<br />

of alertness on the part of entrepreneurs in discovering<br />

new opportunities for profit.<br />

Hayek and Kirzner emphasized that competition is an<br />

open-ended process and doubted the realism of perfectly<br />

competitive models. Under perfect competition, competition<br />

is an end state where all individuals know who their best<br />

potential trading partners are. By focusing on continuous discovery,<br />

Hayek and Kirzner demonstrated the importance of<br />

competition as a means of collecting the information that the<br />

perfect competition concept takes for granted.<br />

The importance of advertising to competition was discussed<br />

by George Stigler and Lester Telser, who demonstrated<br />

that advertising acted as a means of reducing the<br />

costs of gathering information. To Stigler and Telser, advertising<br />

fosters competition by informing individuals about<br />

the opportunities that await them in markets.<br />

Some economists have noted that in some markets natural<br />

barriers to entry and exit limit competition and may<br />

even result in the formation of private monopolies.<br />

Although this concern is legitimate, there are two important<br />

points to keep in mind. First, as economist William Baumol<br />

has argued, potential competition can work just as well as<br />

actual competition. In some cases, monopolies may form,<br />

although it is possible for other sellers to enter the market.<br />

In such instances, monopolists (in the sense of single sellers<br />

in the market) will price their products as if they in fact<br />

had competitors. In other words, monopolists who fear<br />

potential competition will charge competitive prices to prevent<br />

entry by competitors. Because the primary complaint<br />

about monopolies is that they charge prices above competitive<br />

levels, it makes little sense for anyone to worry about<br />

monopolies that use low prices as a barrier to entry.<br />

Second, even if a monopolist secures another type of<br />

barrier to entry and sets prices above competitive levels,<br />

this fact does not imply that there is no competition.<br />

Instead, these situations generally imply that competition<br />

has moved to a different level. Barriers to market entry are<br />

seldom free and generally require maintenance. Demsetz<br />

points out that if some companies have higher profits than<br />

others, it may be because they have some uncapitalized<br />

asset, such as a trademark or goodwill. Some entrepreneurs<br />

create a barrier to entry through innovation. If an entrepreneur<br />

creates a new product or develops a new technology<br />

that reduces costs, then that entrepreneur is able to charge

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!