15.11.2014 Views

capitalism

capitalism

capitalism

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

30 Bentham, Jeremy (1748–1832)<br />

earn the income necessary to live independently. For those<br />

couples that remain married, earnings can have a significant<br />

effect on the number of children they have and how much<br />

they invest in their offspring’s education. In general, as<br />

wages rise, Becker argued, families will tend to have fewer<br />

children and to invest more in each child’s human capital.<br />

This theory has been borne out by the experience of the<br />

United States, Western Europe, and Japan, where fertility<br />

has generally fallen as wage rates and per capita incomes<br />

have risen.<br />

Becker, like most members of the Chicago School,<br />

regards economics as a value-free, positive science. As<br />

such, his views on public policy issues are generally determined<br />

by empirical results. Still, on most matters, Becker is<br />

strongly supportive of the free market and skeptical of government<br />

intervention.<br />

From 1985 to 2004, Becker wrote a monthly column<br />

for BusinessWeek magazine, the final article of which was<br />

titled “A 19-Year Dialogue on the Power of Incentives.” He<br />

noted there:<br />

Along with many others of my generation, I was a socialist<br />

when I started my university studies. But my first few<br />

economics courses taught me the power of competition,<br />

markets, and incentives, and I quickly became a classical<br />

liberal. That means someone who believes in the power of<br />

individual responsibility, a market economy, and a crucial<br />

but limited role of government.<br />

Many of those columns are collected in the 1996 volume,<br />

The Economics of Life, coauthored with his wife,<br />

Guity Nashat Becker. Since December 2004, Becker and<br />

Richard Posner—a member of the faculty at the University<br />

of Chicago Law School, a federal circuit court judge, and a<br />

founder of the law-and-economics movement—have maintained<br />

a blog, where they each publish a short weekly essay<br />

on a timely policy issue.<br />

Those heavily influenced by Becker include Steven<br />

Levitt, professor of economics at Chicago and coauthor of<br />

the best-selling book, Freakonomics: A Rogue Economist<br />

Explores the Hidden Side of Everything. According to<br />

Levitt, “the science of economics is primarily a set of tools,<br />

as opposed to a subject matter,” which means that “no subject...need<br />

be beyond its reach.” Levitt, appropriately, is<br />

director of the Becker Center on Chicago Price Theory.<br />

Becker is arguably the most ambitious and creative<br />

economist of his generation. Although not as famous as his<br />

mentor, Milton Friedman, Becker’s influence may ultimately<br />

rival Friedman’s. As the late George Stigler noted,<br />

“Gary Becker may well go down in history as the chief<br />

architect of a truly general science of society.”<br />

See also Economics, Chicago School of; Family; Friedman, Milton;<br />

Posner, Richard; Racism<br />

AS<br />

Further Readings<br />

Becker, Gary S. The Economic Approach to Human Behavior.<br />

Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1976.<br />

———. The Economics of Discrimination. Chicago: University of<br />

Chicago Press, 1957.<br />

———. Human Capital. New York: Columbia University Press, 1964.<br />

———. A Treatise on the Family. Chicago: University of Chicago<br />

Press, 1981.<br />

Becker, Gary S., and Guity Nashat Becker. The Economics of Life.<br />

New York: McGraw-Hill, 1996.<br />

Febrero, Ramón, and Pedro S. Schwartz, eds. The Essence of<br />

Becker. Stanford, CA: Hoover Institution, 1995.<br />

BENTHAM, JEREMY (1748–1832)<br />

Jeremy Bentham is known today chiefly as the father of<br />

utilitarianism. During his lifetime, Bentham was famous as<br />

the proponent of a scientific approach to social reform.<br />

Born in London, the son of an attorney, Bentham was a<br />

precocious child. He studied at Westminster school and<br />

Queen’s College in Oxford, England. In 1763, he began the<br />

study of law at Lincoln’s Inn, but spent much time carrying<br />

out chemical experiments in his chambers. In December of<br />

that year, he attended the Oxford lectures of England’s most<br />

famous lawyer, Sir William Blackstone, author of the<br />

celebrated Commentaries on the Laws of England. He<br />

remarked later that he had immediately detected the fallacies<br />

in Blackstone’s arguments. In 1776, he fiercely attacked<br />

the Commentaries for being hostile to reform in his first<br />

published book, Fragment on Government. In A Defence of<br />

Usury (1787), he argued that it was a mistake for governments<br />

to prohibit high interest rates because individuals<br />

are the best judges of what will benefit them. His major<br />

work, An Introduction to the Principles of Morals and<br />

Legislation, was published in 1789. Other significant publications<br />

include A Catechism of Parliamentary Reform<br />

(1817, written in 1809), The Rationale of Reward (1825),<br />

The Rationale of Punishment (1830), the Book of Fallacies<br />

(1824), and the Rationale of Judicial Evidence (1827).<br />

Several of Bentham’s writings were first published in<br />

French, and he was made an honorary citizen of France,<br />

with which he had close ties.<br />

In Bentham’s time, law, judicial procedures, and life in<br />

general were governed, to a much greater degree than in our<br />

own, by historical precedent and beliefs not subjected to<br />

critical examination. We owe much of the difference<br />

between his time and ours to Bentham. Bentham was a man<br />

of the Age of Reason; his models were such figures as John<br />

Locke (especially Locke’s Essay Concerning Human<br />

Understanding), Claude Adrien Helvetius, and Voltaire,<br />

and his principal goal was to replace the traditional reliance<br />

on custom with rational analysis. Bentham argued that a<br />

policy or procedure was in accordance with reason when it

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!