15.11.2014 Views

capitalism

capitalism

capitalism

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Ricardo, David (1772–1823) 433<br />

had met the tests of Sidney, Locke, and John Milton,<br />

who believed that the overthrow of governments<br />

required significant justification, requiring “a long train<br />

of Abuses, Prevarications, and Artifices,” as Locke<br />

wrote. In such instances, he maintained, people have as<br />

much right to overturn their government as a ship’s passengers<br />

do to mutiny when the captain of their vessel,<br />

despite contrary winds, leaks, and low supplies, steers<br />

them into a hurricane.<br />

Because neither ruler nor ruled should be subject to<br />

arbitrary action, singular instances of government injustice<br />

should be met with personal resistance instead of revolution.<br />

Good governments listen to the governed and revise<br />

unjust laws. Political authorities “who know the frailty of<br />

human nature will always distrust their own,” Sidney contended,<br />

“and desiring only to do what they ought, will be<br />

glad to be restrained from that which they ought not to do.”<br />

Likewise, people tend to restrain themselves from rash<br />

action. “Revolutions happen not upon every little mismanagement<br />

in publick affairs,” Locke maintained, for even<br />

“great mistakes” of rulers will be endured by the people<br />

“without mutiny or murder.” Only when regimes ignore or<br />

outlaw all criticism, public protest, and other forms of resistance<br />

may the people turn to violent resistance.<br />

If these theorists are correct, then one of the most powerful<br />

safeguards of individual rights—as well as of law and<br />

order—is a society’s recognition of the right of revolution.<br />

The public’s willingness to exercise this right discourages<br />

government officials from ignoring their most basic obligations<br />

to the governed.<br />

See also American Revolution; Glorious Revolution; Jefferson,<br />

Thomas; Locke, John; Secessionism<br />

Further Readings<br />

RMD<br />

Bailyn, Bernard. The Ideological Origins of the<br />

American Revolution. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University<br />

Press, 1967.<br />

Brooks, David L., ed. From Magna Carta to the Constitution:<br />

Documents in the Struggle for Liberty. San Francisco: Fox &<br />

Wilkes, 1993.<br />

Locke, John. Two Treatises of Government. Cambridge: Cambridge<br />

University Press, 1988.<br />

Rossiter, Clinton. Seedtime of the Republic: The Origin of the<br />

American Tradition of Political Liberty. New York: Harcourt,<br />

Brace, 1953.<br />

Sidney, Algernon. Discourses Concerning Government. Indianapolis,<br />

IN: Liberty Fund, 1990.<br />

Trenchard, John, and Thomas Gordon. Cato’s Letters or Essays on<br />

Liberty, Civil and Religious, and Other Important Subjects.<br />

Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Fund, 1990.<br />

Tuck, Richard. Natural Rights Theories: Their Origin and<br />

Development. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1979.<br />

RICARDO, DAVID (1772–1823)<br />

David Ricardo was a brilliant classical economist. His policies<br />

of free trade and hard money helped propel Britain into<br />

its role as “workshop of the world” and as an industrial<br />

giant, yet his labor theory of value and antagonistic model<br />

of <strong>capitalism</strong> proved misguided and gave unexpected support<br />

to the Marxists and socialists.<br />

Born in London to a large Jewish family, Ricardo made<br />

his fortune when a relatively young man as a stockbroker<br />

on the London Stock Exchange. He was a speculator par<br />

excellence, allegedly making a million pounds sterling in<br />

1 day following the Battle of Waterloo. In 1815, he purchased<br />

a large estate called Gatcomb Park in Gloucestershire and<br />

devoted the remainder of his life to intellectual interests. In<br />

1819, he was elected to Parliament. Four years later, at the<br />

age of 51, he died suddenly of an ear infection.<br />

In the 1810s, Ricardo wrote a series of essays and books<br />

promoting laissez-faire. He argued that England’s raging<br />

inflationary price spiral was caused by the Bank of England<br />

issuing excessive bank notes to pay for the war against France.<br />

Ricardo’s hard-money views eventually led to England adopting<br />

the classical gold standard and 100% reserve gold backing<br />

of its currency, with the Peel Act of 1844. He vigorously<br />

attacked the Corn Laws, England’s notorious high tariff wall<br />

on wheat and other agricultural goods, which was ultimately<br />

repealed in 1846. He made profound contributions to economics,<br />

including the laws of comparative advantage, diminishing<br />

returns, and the quantity theory of money.<br />

He is considered the inventor of abstract model building<br />

in economics, creating a mathematical model with a few<br />

simple variables, a technique used later by such diverse<br />

economists as Karl Marx, John Maynard Keynes, Paul<br />

Samuelson, and Milton Friedman.<br />

But it was this abstract reasoning that also has been<br />

called the “Ricardian Vice.” In his work On the Principles<br />

of Political Economy and Taxation (1817), Ricardo created<br />

an oversimplified “corn” model that led to an antagonistic<br />

view of <strong>capitalism</strong>, where values are determined by labor<br />

inputs and where wages can only increase at the expense of<br />

profits. His analysis of the nature of production concluded<br />

that wages tend toward subsistence levels, known as the iron<br />

law of wages. Ricardo thought that over time, as the population<br />

grew, an increased demand for food would have the<br />

natural effect of raising its price, which would lead to an<br />

increase in the value of labor. Yet any increase in the value<br />

of labor, Ricardo concluded, must invariably lead to a fall in<br />

profits. Ricardo’s dismal science, together with the doctrines<br />

of his friend, Thomas Malthus, moved economics away<br />

from Adam Smith’s invisible hand with its harmony of interests<br />

and onto a path of class antagonism and exploitation,<br />

giving ammunition to socialist and Marxist causes.<br />

MaS

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!