15.11.2014 Views

capitalism

capitalism

capitalism

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Economics, Chicago School of 135<br />

Mises and Hayek warned. The reason that both models<br />

failed to achieve the level of economic prosperity promised<br />

was because of what these approaches—market socialism<br />

and Keynesian demand management—had assumed away.<br />

In both instances, the models were predicated on the<br />

assumptions that they sought to prove. Government officials<br />

were assumed to be both benevolent and to possess<br />

omniscience, which allowed the government to be<br />

employed as a corrective to perceived failures. It is almost<br />

certainly because of this intellectual history that Austrian<br />

writers have tended to focus their applied economics on<br />

issues of socialism and macroeconomics.<br />

Macro models suffered the same problems as did models<br />

of market socialism and were plagued by unwarranted<br />

assumptions and excessive aggregation. Classic works in<br />

Austrian macroeconomics by Mises and Hayek were<br />

largely written before the Keynesian hegemony in economics,<br />

which lasted from the 1940s to the mid-1970s. A<br />

younger generation of Austrian economists, however, was<br />

inspired by these classics, the work on monetary theory,<br />

and the business cycle by Murray Rothbard, which sought<br />

to develop further the insights first offered by Mises and<br />

Hayek. They have pioneered work in the area of free banking<br />

and challenged the idea that unregulated banking would<br />

be chaotic. More recent work has challenged the theoretical<br />

coherence of the contending macroeconomic models and<br />

argued that, rather than a labor-based approach, macroeconomics<br />

should restructure its analysis to be capital-based.<br />

The most significant shortcoming of standard macroeconomics<br />

in all its varieties is the slight attention that is paid<br />

to capital theory. Roger Garrison has dubbed this laborbased<br />

macro, as opposed to the more Austrian style capitalbased<br />

macro. The main issue here is not simply a focus on<br />

capital markets, but the way the capital markets are conceived.<br />

Austrian economists view capital not as a stream of<br />

financial resources, but as a structure of capital goods that<br />

must be coordinated in the process of production through<br />

time. Capital goods are heterogeneous and have multiple<br />

specific uses, and Austrians have traced in detail the important<br />

role of capital goods and capital accounting in a modern<br />

economy.<br />

With respect to my original question regarding what<br />

continues to make Austrian economics a worthwhile<br />

approach to the study of the production and distribution of<br />

goods and services, several economists have attempted to<br />

answer this question by way of the biography of a set of<br />

ideas and by developing these ideas in the hope that they<br />

will transform economic scholarship. This approach<br />

springs from an honest commitment to the belief that the<br />

Austrian school provides us with a better opportunity to<br />

gain truth in economic understanding. It is an approach to<br />

economics that is grounded in the choices of human beings.<br />

It shies away from heroic assumptions, and it does not<br />

begin every analysis by postulating an asymmetry between<br />

private and public actors. Instead, the same foibles and<br />

weaknesses that might be attributed to people in the private<br />

sector are equally assumed in describing those in the public<br />

sector. The difference in the conclusions of the comparative<br />

analysis between private and public actors is a function of<br />

the institutional environment within which choices are<br />

made. In the absence of an institutional environment of<br />

secure private-property rights, freedom of price negotiation,<br />

accurate profit and loss accounting, and nondiscretionary<br />

politics, the promise of material progress and social<br />

cooperation will go unrealized.<br />

The Austrian School of Economics provides a set of<br />

utilitarian arguments in support of a classical liberal order<br />

that are indispensable for those who place a high value on<br />

human liberty. However, it is important to stress that these<br />

arguments are a consequence of the analysis that Austrians<br />

undertake and not presumptions that they hold before the<br />

analysis. Austrian economics is not synonymous with libertarianism.<br />

Rather, it is a scientific body of thought that,<br />

when combined with some ethical precepts, leads to a<br />

strong argument for a libertarian society.<br />

See also Banking, Austrian Theory of; Böhm-Bawerk, Eugen von;<br />

Hayek, Friedrich A.; Individualism, Methodological; Kirzner,<br />

Israel M.; Mises, Ludwig von; Praxeology; Rothbard, Murray;<br />

Socialist Calculation Debate; Spontaneous Order<br />

Further Readings<br />

PJB<br />

Boettke, Peter. Coordination and Calculation: Essays on Socialism<br />

and Transitional Political Economy. New York: Routledge, 2001.<br />

———, ed. Socialism and the Market: The Socialist Calculation<br />

Debate Revisited. 9 vols. New York: Routledge, 2000.<br />

Hayek, F. A. Individualism and Economic Order. Chicago:<br />

University of Chicago Press, 1948.<br />

Horwitz, S. Microfoundations and Macroeconomics. New York:<br />

Routledge, 2000.<br />

Kirzner, I. Competition and Entrepreneurship. Chicago: University<br />

of Chicago Press, 1973.<br />

Lachmann, L. Capital and Its Structure. Kansas City, MO: Sheed<br />

Andrews McMeel, 1977 [1956].<br />

Lewin, P. Capital in Disequilibrium. New York: Routledge, 1999.<br />

O’Driscoll, G., and M. Rizzo. The Economics of Time and<br />

Ignorance. 2nd ed. New York: Routledge, 1995.<br />

Rothbard, Murray. America’s Great Depression. Princeton, NJ: Van<br />

Nostrand Press, 1963.<br />

Selgin, G. The Theory of Free Banking. Totowa, NJ: Rowman &<br />

Littlefield, 1988.<br />

ECONOMICS, CHICAGO SCHOOL OF<br />

The Chicago School of Economics refers to that group of<br />

economists associated with the University of Chicago and<br />

most closely identified with the work of Milton Friedman

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!