15.11.2014 Views

capitalism

capitalism

capitalism

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Free Trade 189<br />

occur daily in markets coalesce into a vast productive order.<br />

If history is a guide, a free-market economy ensures continual<br />

improvement in humankind’s material welfare.<br />

See also Civil Society; Decentralism; Entrepreneurship; Laissez-<br />

Faire Policy; Private Property; Wealth and Poverty<br />

Further Readings<br />

DJB<br />

Cox, W. Michael, and Richard Alm. Myths of Rich & Poor. New<br />

York: Basic Books, 1999.<br />

Hayek, F. A. “The Use of Knowledge in Society.” Individualism and<br />

Economic Order. F. A. Hayek, ed. Chicago: University of<br />

Chicago Press, 1948. 77–91.<br />

Kirzner, Israel M. How Markets Work. London: Institute of<br />

Economic Affairs, 1997.<br />

Lebergott, Stanley. Pursuing Happiness. Princeton, NJ: Princeton<br />

University Press, 1993.<br />

Polanyi, Karl. The Great Transformation. New York: Octagon<br />

Books, 1975.<br />

Rand, Ayn. Capitalism: The Unknown Ideal. New York: Penguin<br />

Putnam, 1986.<br />

FREE TRADE<br />

Free trade means the exchange of goods and services across<br />

international borders, unhindered by government tariffs,<br />

quotas, or other restrictions. Since the publication of The<br />

Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith in 1776, the debate over<br />

free trade has been one of the major battlegrounds in the<br />

broader controversy about economic freedom. Free trade is<br />

an essential component of globalization, which includes not<br />

only trade, but the international flow of capital and people<br />

and the resulting integration of national economies with<br />

each other.<br />

Free trade has been a central tenet of the libertarian,<br />

or classical liberal, philosophy for centuries. The same<br />

philosophical and economic arguments for the freedom of<br />

exchange within a national economy apply equally to<br />

exchange across international borders. According to libertarian<br />

principles, workers should be free to voluntarily<br />

exchange the fruits of their labors with others for mutual<br />

benefit, whether the trading partner lives across the road or<br />

across an ocean. The increased competition occasioned by<br />

free trade can indeed result in some domestic industries losing<br />

market share and workers temporarily losing jobs, but<br />

advocates of free trade see this loss as a normal and healthy<br />

outcome of free-market competition.<br />

Mankind has always engaged in trade. Even in the poorest<br />

societies, households have traded with one another, and<br />

rural farmers have traded with city dwellers. However, natural<br />

barriers, long distances, and government controls have<br />

hindered international trade throughout much of mankind’s<br />

history. Despite those obstacles, trade flourished in the<br />

Mediterranean basin for centuries before the rise of the<br />

Roman Empire, reaching its height in the 2nd and 3rd<br />

centuries A.D., while during the late Middle Ages, the<br />

member states of the Hanseatic League were engaged in a<br />

burgeoning trade in the Baltic and North Seas. During that<br />

same time, Venice thrived as the center of the overland<br />

spice trade from Asia. Venetian traders pioneered foreign<br />

exchange, bank loans, accounting, and letters of credit.<br />

Spices and manufactured goods were the staple of trade in<br />

the Mediterranean, whereas lumber, fish, wool, and hides<br />

were the chief commodities of trade in Northern Europe.<br />

The voyages of discovery in the 15th and 16th centuries<br />

opened new routes among Europe, the New World of the<br />

Americas, and the markets of South and East Asia, ushering<br />

in the Mercantilist Era. The discoveries and dramatic<br />

expansion of sea-going trade were made possible by the<br />

development of three-masted ships, called carracks, which<br />

could sail more sharply into the wind and made shipping<br />

less dependent on seasonal trade winds. The leading trading<br />

nations of that era, which lasted until about 1800, were<br />

Spain and Portugal, followed by the Dutch Republic and<br />

then France and Great Britain. As trade grew, so did government<br />

intervention. According to the prevailing mercantilist<br />

ideas at the time, exports were preferable to imports<br />

because they better enabled governments to acquire and<br />

accumulate gold, the universal currency of the day. As a<br />

result, a web of national laws evolved that hindered trade in<br />

a broad range of goods, but especially manufactured items.<br />

Against this backdrop, Adam Smith published his magisterial<br />

work, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the<br />

Wealth of Nations. Smith argued, with systematic logic and<br />

illuminating examples, that a nation’s wealth is not measured<br />

by its stockpile of gold, but by the ability of its people<br />

to produce goods and services of value to others. Nations<br />

raise their productivity through the division of labor, with<br />

households, regions, and nations specializing in what they<br />

do best. Trade allowed the creation of more wealth by<br />

expanding the size of the market, thus allowing a finer division<br />

of labor among and within nations. As Smith famously<br />

observed in Book IV,<br />

It is the maxim of every prudent master of a family, never<br />

to attempt to make at home what it will cost him more to<br />

make than to buy. ...What is prudence in the conduct of<br />

every private family, can scarce be folly in that of a great<br />

kingdom. If a foreign country can supply us with a commodity<br />

cheaper than we ourselves can make it, better buy<br />

it of them with some part of the produce of our own industry,<br />

employed in a way in which we have some advantage.<br />

The intellectual argument for free trade was fortified in<br />

1817 when British stockbroker David Ricardo first explained<br />

the theory of “comparative advantage.” According to this<br />

theory, even if a nation’s workers can produce everything

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!