15.11.2014 Views

capitalism

capitalism

capitalism

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

122 Development, Economic<br />

The debt crisis revealed that a lack of capital was not a<br />

problem for the Third World. Rather, economic mismanagement<br />

and the domestic policy environment were at fault.<br />

Highly indebted South Korea did not experience economic<br />

crisis as did highly indebted Latin American countries.<br />

Thus, by the early 1980s, Deepak Lal was moved to declare<br />

“the poverty of development economics.” A worldwide<br />

move to the market slowly began and by the early 1990s<br />

accelerated in pace and scope, including most of the formerly<br />

socialist countries.<br />

The early liberalizers set a pattern of development that<br />

other countries have emulated with varying degrees of success.<br />

From 1960 to 2000, the four Asian tigers maintained<br />

average annual per-person growth rates of more than 5%,<br />

increasing their income by at least seven times, with Hong<br />

Kong and Singapore surpassing the United Kingdom.<br />

Likewise, reform pioneers Chile and China began liberalizing<br />

their economies in the 1970s with notable results.<br />

Chile’s per capita income is now more than 3 times greater<br />

than in 1975, whereas China’s income is nearly 10 times<br />

higher than when reforms began.<br />

The era of globalization has produced other reform successes<br />

in countries as diverse as Vietnam, El Salvador,<br />

Ireland, and Estonia. Central European nations have succeeded<br />

in introducing policies of political and economic<br />

liberalization, putting them on a convergence path with<br />

Western Europe. Yet other countries—in Latin America and<br />

in the former Soviet Union, for example—have had a more<br />

difficult time implementing coherent reforms and sustaining<br />

high growth. Most of sub-Saharan Africa and much of<br />

the Middle East have yet to see significant economic<br />

reform. Mainly because of their economic policies, Africans<br />

are poorer today than they were 30 years ago.<br />

The era of globalization has also renewed an interest in<br />

domestic institutions, such as the rule of law, and other factors<br />

that could explain widely different reform experiences.<br />

The International Monetary Fund estimated, for example,<br />

that if institutions in Africa were brought up to the level in<br />

emerging Asia, African long-term per capita income would<br />

nearly double. The Fraser Institute’s annual Economic<br />

Freedom of the World report—the most systematic longterm<br />

study measuring policies and institutions consistent<br />

with personal choice, voluntary exchange, protection of<br />

private property, and freedom to compete—finds a strong<br />

empirical relationship between economic freedom and<br />

prosperity. Countries that are more economically free tend<br />

to be wealthier and grow faster. That relationship remains<br />

even after taking into account other factors such as education<br />

or demographic indicators.<br />

Poor countries that move in the direction of economic<br />

freedom in a significant way, as China and India have<br />

done, tend to enjoy fast growth and are thus catching up<br />

to rich countries. Annual per capita growth rates of more<br />

than 8% since the early 1980s and about 5% since the<br />

early 1990s in China and India, respectively, have pulled<br />

hundreds of millions of people from poverty and reversed<br />

the centuries-long growth of world income inequality.<br />

Greater economic freedom also is strongly related<br />

to improvements in the range of human development<br />

indicators—longevity, access to safe drinking water, infant<br />

mortality rates, environmental quality, and so on. During<br />

the past several decades, the gap in human well-being<br />

between poor and rich countries has been closing dramatically<br />

and at a faster pace than the gap in incomes. The advantage<br />

of underdevelopment today is that poor countries can<br />

grow at much faster rates than was the case for rich countries<br />

when they were at similar stages of development. Moreover,<br />

for a given income level, countries enjoy notably higher<br />

standards of living than was the case even 30 years ago.<br />

More economic freedom in the world appears to be benefiting<br />

even those countries that have done little to reform.<br />

The development consensus now generally favors marketoriented<br />

policies and institutions that constrain political power<br />

and support market exchange. Although we know that institutions<br />

matter, there is no consensus on how to promote the right<br />

institutional or policy environment. The difficulty that countries<br />

as different as Russia, Argentina, and Malawi have had in<br />

successfully introducing reforms has generated an awareness<br />

of institutional inertia and the role of institutions in shaping<br />

political behavior and seemingly enduring power structures.<br />

Development appears to be more a political than an economic<br />

challenge. The recognition that institutional change<br />

is more complex and occurs at a slower pace than policy<br />

change has led to pessimism among some observers about<br />

the prospects of development in many parts of the world.<br />

Yet precisely because institutional change takes time, such<br />

conclusions may be premature. It took about eight centuries<br />

for the institutions supportive of market exchange and the<br />

rule of law to develop in the West. By contrast, the current<br />

era of liberal reforms is still only a few decades old and<br />

may already be leading to incipient institutional and cultural<br />

change in countries that have recently begun opening<br />

their economies. The 21st century will tell whether the case<br />

for optimism is stronger than the case for pessimism.<br />

The thinking regarding economic development has<br />

matured and has involved a rediscovery of classical liberal<br />

insights into the causes of prosperity. Experts have a greater<br />

appreciation of the limits of development economics and its<br />

ability to forcibly promote growth; of the relevance of the<br />

development path of advanced economies to developing<br />

countries; of the role of local knowledge and of incentives<br />

on individual and entrepreneurial behavior; and of the complex<br />

influence that institutions, culture, geography, history,<br />

political regimes, and other factors exert on each other and<br />

on growth. As such, the study of development has become<br />

qualitative and multidisciplinary, drawing on work from<br />

economic historians, legal scholars, anthropologists, and<br />

political scientists.<br />

Despite those advances, a political push led by international<br />

organizations such as the United Nations and the

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!