15.11.2014 Views

capitalism

capitalism

capitalism

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

134 Economics, Austrian School of<br />

world of uncertainty. Action is directed at an unknown<br />

future and logically must be; if the future were known, there<br />

could be no way in which human action could affect the outcome.<br />

As Mises puts it: “The uncertainty of the future is<br />

already implied in the very notion of action. That man acts<br />

and that the future is uncertain are by no means two independent<br />

matters. They are only two different modes of<br />

establishing one thing.”<br />

The market process emerges out of the interaction of<br />

human actors. We can conceive of the market process in a<br />

way best explicated by Israel Kirzner in his book The<br />

Meaning of Market Process. There are two sets of variables<br />

in economic life, Kirzner argues. There are the underlying<br />

variables of tastes, technology, and endowment of natural<br />

resources, and there are the induced variables of prices,<br />

profit, and loss. In competitive equilibrium, the induced<br />

variables of the market correspond perfectly to the underlying<br />

variables, such that all resources are utilized in such a<br />

way that the highest value is achieved and the least costly<br />

technologies are employed. When the market is in competitive<br />

equilibrium, it simultaneously realizes production efficiency,<br />

exchange efficiency, and product-mix efficiency. In<br />

short, given the conditions of the world, one could not better<br />

arrange these variables even were an omnipotent being<br />

to do so.<br />

Critics of economics emphasize the highly specific<br />

conditions required for this simultaneous achievement of<br />

efficiency. These critics tend to deny that there is any relationship<br />

among the underlying variables of tastes, technology,<br />

and resource endowment, on the one hand, and the<br />

induced variables of monetary prices, profit, and loss, on<br />

the other hand. Without postulating an intimate relationship<br />

between the underlying and the induced variables, it is<br />

argued, the efficiency properties of the market cannot be<br />

sustained. The Austrians have mediated this debate<br />

between the perfect and imperfect markets by maintaining<br />

that, although induced variables do not perfectly map the<br />

underlying variables, nevertheless they are closely related.<br />

Economics is not a science about exact points, but instead<br />

a science of tendency and direction. A lagged relationship<br />

exists between the two sets of variables. To the extent that<br />

the induced variables of the market do not reflect the underlying<br />

variables, there will exist opportunities for pure profit<br />

for those who move in the direction of narrowing the gaps<br />

between the two. Ironically, if all actors knew of these<br />

opportunities, then no profit would be realized because<br />

profit opportunities that are known to all will be realized by<br />

none. Austrianism postulates that no knowledge is perfectly<br />

known to all. Instead, knowledge is divided among market<br />

participants and must be communicated through the activities<br />

of economic agents and through the institutions of the<br />

market system. In the absence of any change in the underlying<br />

variables, the induced variables of the market will<br />

move in the direction of dovetailing with them. However,<br />

because tastes and technology are constantly changing as<br />

circumstances change, a perfect correspondence of economic<br />

variables and plans is impossible. Nevertheless, economic<br />

analysis is able to inform us on how any state of<br />

affairs outside of perfect correspondence will provide<br />

incentives and information for actors to move in the direction<br />

that would result in such perfection were it not for<br />

intervening changes in the underlying variables.<br />

This emphasis on the mechanics that encourage adaptation<br />

to changing conditions requires not only a different<br />

way to do economic science, but also a different set of economic<br />

arguments that point to the benefits of markets. In<br />

the canonical general equilibrium model, for example, the<br />

plans of economic agents are prereconciled, such that the<br />

market is said to clear. This approach highlights the interconnectedness<br />

of all economic activities and represents one<br />

of the great intellectual achievements in the field of economics<br />

of the 19th and early 20th centuries. Yet the equilibrium<br />

approach tends to preclude from analysis the very<br />

activities that enable markets to emerge and work effectively<br />

to coordinate the plans of economic actors. The most<br />

obvious activity that must be eliminated in equilibrium<br />

analysis is the entrepreneurial discovery of pure economic<br />

profits because economic profits, by definition, are zero<br />

when all aspects of the economy are in equilibrium.<br />

One of the implications of eliminating the entrepreneur as<br />

a central character in economic analysis is that competition is<br />

given a different meaning, as Frank Machovec has pointed<br />

out in his book Perfect Competition and the Transformation<br />

of Economics (1995). The economist’s notion of competition<br />

differs from its common usage. In ordinary parlance, competition<br />

is a term used to connote an activity. Thus, to compete<br />

is used when we wish to refer to two teams vying to win a<br />

game. However, when an economist uses the term, it is more<br />

than likely used as a noun to describe a state of affairs. The<br />

contrast between these two meanings of the term is no more<br />

evident than it was in the antitrust case brought by the Justice<br />

Department against Microsoft. It is hardly the case that only<br />

Austrian economists have supported Microsoft against an<br />

overzealous government. Indeed, perhaps the most able critics<br />

of the government’s case are Stanley Leibowitz and<br />

Stephen Margolis, whose book, Winners, Losers &<br />

Microsoft, argued the case in terms of equilibrium economics.<br />

However, a significant aspect of their analysis turns not<br />

on equilibrium economics, but on human imagination and<br />

entrepreneurial activity.<br />

One of the primary reasons that the Austrians are so sensitive<br />

to these issues in ways that other economists are not<br />

is because of the debates these economists were embroiled<br />

from the 1930s to the 1950s. The Austrian economists, in<br />

particular Mises and Hayek, led the intellectual opposition<br />

to the new models of market socialism and Keynesian<br />

demand management. The Austrians were perceived by<br />

most economists and the general public to have lost both<br />

debates. However, both the market socialists and Keynesian<br />

models failed utterly as guides to enhance prosperity, as

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!