15.11.2014 Views

capitalism

capitalism

capitalism

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

284 Law and Economics<br />

Spaniards living in the New World could only trade with<br />

the motherland and also were banned from trading with<br />

other colonies.<br />

Las Casas, in contrast, is an unlikely figure given his<br />

fame as a champion of individual rights inasmuch as he was<br />

an orthodox Catholic. He did not depart from his creed,<br />

which today would be regarded as radically conservative in<br />

values and religion, while his views on economics were<br />

close to those of classical liberalism. However, Las Casas’s<br />

self-adulatory but engaging propagandist style and rhetorical<br />

skills, in addition to his indiscriminate attack on powerful<br />

figures of his day, lent his writings to those who later<br />

sought to manipulate the public. By manumitting his slaves<br />

and foregoing a search for economic or social power, he<br />

lent credibility to his popular, yet sometimes exaggerated,<br />

accounts.<br />

See also Imperialism; Racism; Rights, Natural; Slavery, World;<br />

Scholastics/School of Salamanca<br />

Further Readings<br />

AlC<br />

Hanke, Lewis. All Mankind Is One: A Study of the Disputation<br />

between Bartolomé de Las Casas and Juan Gins de Sepulveda in<br />

1550 on the Intellectual and Religious Capacity of the American<br />

Indians. DeKalb: Northern Illinois University Press, 1974.<br />

Watner, Carl. “‘All Mankind Is One’: The Libertarian Tradition in<br />

Sixteenth-Century Spain.” Journal of Libertarian Studies 2 no. 8<br />

(Summer 1987): 293–309.<br />

LAW AND ECONOMICS<br />

Economists have long offered insight into the law. With<br />

respect to libertarianism and the analysis of the market,<br />

Nobel laureate Friedrich von Hayek’s definitive works The<br />

Constitution of Liberty and Law, Legislation, and Liberty<br />

applied crucial insights from the Austrian School of<br />

Economics to legal issues. On the left, John R. Commons of<br />

the University of Wisconsin, in his The Legal Foundations<br />

of Capitalism (1921) and other works, applied economic<br />

analysis to legal institutions. A number of other economists<br />

also have dealt with legal issues, among them Nobel laureate<br />

Gary Becker’s pioneering work on issues centering on discrimination<br />

and family law. During the 1960s and 1970s,<br />

however, a group of scholars went beyond simply applying<br />

economic insights to legal issues and developed a body of<br />

work that became the known as the law and economics<br />

movement. The emergence of this movement was one of the<br />

most important developments in 20th-century legal thought.<br />

Indeed, Professor Ian MacNeil, despite being critical of<br />

many aspects of the movement, called law and economics<br />

“the most powerful single monofocused discipline in<br />

American legal studies.” Largely associated with the<br />

University of Chicago during its early days, scholars who<br />

have centered their study on the interrelationship between<br />

law and economics today apply a variety of methodologies to<br />

bring the tools of economic analysis to bear on legal issues.<br />

Two individuals dominated this movement. Ronald<br />

Coase, who was awarded the Nobel Prize in 1991, and<br />

author of a pathbreaking article in the field, “The Problem<br />

of Social Cost,” is often credited with initiating this<br />

approach in 1960. He was quickly joined by University of<br />

Chicago law professor Richard Posner, who is currently a<br />

judge on the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Seventh Circuit.<br />

Posner, through numerous articles and books and his definitive<br />

treatise, the Economic Analysis of Law, has played a<br />

major role in expanding the parameters of the field.<br />

Coase’s contribution cannot be understated. “The<br />

Problem of Social Cost,” one of the most often cited articles<br />

in both economics and law, laid most of the intellectual<br />

groundwork for many of later developments in the field.<br />

Coase wrote the article as a response to the earlier work by<br />

A. C. Pigou, which was crucial in structuring modern welfare<br />

economics. In the 1920s, Pigou pioneered the analysis<br />

of market failures and focused on the most appropriate<br />

means of correcting these failures. For example, where a<br />

firm polluted a river with waste water, thus imposing costs<br />

on downstream users, the appropriate response had been to<br />

create a tax on waste water that brought the firm’s private<br />

costs into line with the social costs of its behavior.<br />

Pigouvian solutions are correspondingly heavily reliant on<br />

central government intervention. Coase’s analysis, in contrast,<br />

focused on the allocation of property rights. If downstream<br />

entities held a right to receive unpolluted water, they<br />

would be in a position to then use the legal system to force<br />

the upstream polluter to pay damages or stop to polluting.<br />

The solution to “market failures” thus lay with better definition<br />

of property rights, not corrective taxes.<br />

Equally important, Coase took his analysis a step further<br />

by showing that, at least in economic terms, the precise<br />

allocation of property rights was irrelevant to the parties<br />

involved reaching a solution. Nor does it matter if property<br />

rights are allocated to the upstream polluter or to the downstream<br />

user because in either case having a clear property<br />

right would produce an equally efficient solution. If the<br />

gains from polluting the river outweighed the harms done<br />

to the downstream user, the two parties would be able to<br />

negotiate a transfer of the rights to the polluter regardless of<br />

where the right originated. If the costs of the pollution were<br />

to outweigh the gains, the inverse would hold true. The<br />

problem was thus reciprocal and not one-sided.<br />

Finally, and most significant, Coase used these insights<br />

to argue that where transaction costs (e.g., the cost of hiring<br />

negotiators, drafting agreements, etc.) were zero, the<br />

same solution would result regardless of who was initially

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!