15.11.2014 Views

capitalism

capitalism

capitalism

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Becker, Gary S. (1930– ) 29<br />

of Chicago. He was an assistant professor at Chicago from<br />

1954 to 1957, before moving to Columbia University and the<br />

National Bureau of Economic Research. “I felt that I would<br />

become intellectually more independent if I left the nest and<br />

had to make it on my own,” Becker has written. “I have<br />

always believed this was the correct decision, for I developed<br />

greater independence and self-confidence than seems likely if<br />

I remained at Chicago.” Becker spent 12 fruitful years at<br />

Columbia, but ultimately returned to Chicago in 1969, where<br />

he has taught ever since.<br />

As the Nobel Prize committee stated, if there is a defining<br />

characteristic of Becker’s work, it is method. He has<br />

applied rational choice theory rigorously and ingeniously to<br />

topics that were once thought beyond the purview of economics.<br />

At the heart of Becker’s approach is the idea that<br />

people, in all areas of their lives, maximize their utility subject<br />

to the constraints with which they are faced. In short,<br />

they act purposefully—rationally—not only in choosing a<br />

job, but also in choosing a mate. These actions are not<br />

always “selfish.” Instead, Becker models behavior in a way<br />

that allows individuals to “maximize welfare as they conceive<br />

it, whether they be selfish, altruistic, loyal, spiteful, or<br />

masochistic.” At first, his work was often viewed with<br />

skepticism by economists, who considered his choice of<br />

subjects odd and far afield from more well-trodden territory<br />

as, say, money and banking, and by sociologists, political<br />

scientists, and anthropologists, who viewed him as an interloper<br />

or, worse, an “imperialist” aiming to apply methods<br />

wholly unsuitable to their disciplines. Over time, however,<br />

his work has become widely accepted by economists, and,<br />

increasingly, social scientists across related fields have<br />

come to appreciate it as well.<br />

Becker’s work has spanned a wide variety of topics, but<br />

his influence arguably has been the greatest in four broad<br />

areas: racial discrimination, crime, human capital, and the<br />

family. When Becker first examined the economics of discrimination<br />

in the 1950s, much of American society was still<br />

segregated. Becker suggested that this fact implied that the<br />

employer who refused to hire African-American workers<br />

had a taste for discrimination. However, that taste, as Becker<br />

demonstrated, is not necessarily costless. In a competitive<br />

market, employers who systematically discriminate against<br />

specific racial or ethnic groups may suffer because the more<br />

productive workers from those groups will likely be hired<br />

by competing firms looking to gain an advantage. The more<br />

competitive the market, the more intense is the bidding for<br />

skilled workers regardless of their race or ethnicity.<br />

Becker followed this analysis with discussions of individual<br />

skill-building or human capital. His conclusions were<br />

straightforward: that skills are, in fact, augmentable, and<br />

individuals face an economic choice about whether and how<br />

to build them. The fundamental issue is opportunity cost.<br />

Suppose one goes to college for 4 years to learn new skills<br />

and ultimately obtain a degree. There are often obvious<br />

costs involved, most significantly tuition. But there are less<br />

obvious costs, such as the time spent pursuing education—<br />

time that could have been spent in the labor market instead,<br />

thus earning wages. Individuals must assess whether the<br />

building of such skills will help them enough over their lifetimes—through<br />

improved earnings as well as cultural and<br />

other nonmonetary gains—to more than offset the time and<br />

effort spent acquiring them. This idea is now one of the most<br />

standard in labor economics—indeed, all of economics—<br />

which was quite novel at the time Becker began his work.<br />

Subsequent empirical studies have shown that the building<br />

of skills has become increasingly important in modern<br />

economies, both at the individual and macro level. Highskilled<br />

workers tend to receive a wage premium, and the<br />

economies of countries with relatively well-educated workforces<br />

tend to grow more quickly than those with relatively<br />

poorly educated workforces. As a result, human capital—<br />

specifically, how to most efficiently encourage investment<br />

in the building of skills—has become an important public<br />

policy issue.<br />

Becker’s work on crime overturned some long-held<br />

beliefs. As he put it: “In the 1950s and 1960s, intellectual<br />

discussions of crime were dominated by the opinion that<br />

criminal behavior was caused by mental illness and social<br />

oppression, and that criminals were helpless ‘victims.’”<br />

Becker was critical of these assumptions. Most criminals,<br />

he argued, were rational, just like noncriminals. He<br />

acknowledged that, in general, people are constrained by<br />

moral and ethical considerations and would not commit<br />

crimes even when those crimes could be quite lucrative and<br />

the chances of being caught are quite low. But for those<br />

who do become criminals, many carefully assess their alternatives.<br />

Given the likelihood of being caught, is crime more<br />

profitable than pursuing work that is legal? If so, they may<br />

choose crime. It is important here to note the linkage with<br />

human capital. Those who have spent time improving their<br />

skills are less likely to pursue crime because their legal<br />

workplace alternatives tend to be better. In addition, they<br />

have more to lose, in both future earnings and social status.<br />

Of all of Becker’s research projects, his work on the<br />

family is perhaps the most controversial. It also has been the<br />

most mentally taxing. “Writing A Treatise on the Family is<br />

the most difficult sustained intellectual effort I have undertaken,”<br />

Becker wrote. Despite its complexity, there are some<br />

key themes that run throughout his work. First is the idea<br />

that the household can be modeled as a small factory, where<br />

decisions about the distribution of work and the allocation<br />

of time are determined by largely economic factors. For<br />

instance, as family members’ real wages increase, there is<br />

less incentive for home production and greater incentive to<br />

work outside the household. This fact explains, in part, the<br />

increase in female labor-force participation. Also, more<br />

women entering the workforce may have contributed to<br />

higher rates of divorce, as they become increasingly able to

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!