11.01.2013 Views

Transportation's Role in Reducing U.S. Greenhouse Gas Emissions ...

Transportation's Role in Reducing U.S. Greenhouse Gas Emissions ...

Transportation's Role in Reducing U.S. Greenhouse Gas Emissions ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

efficiently locate spaces.<br />

Transportation’s <strong>Role</strong> <strong>in</strong> Reduc<strong>in</strong>g U.S. <strong>Greenhouse</strong> <strong>Gas</strong> <strong>Emissions</strong>: Volume 2<br />

Most park<strong>in</strong>g management strategies are under the doma<strong>in</strong> of local government. In most<br />

U.S. cities, park<strong>in</strong>g supply is constra<strong>in</strong>ed or priced only <strong>in</strong> the central bus<strong>in</strong>ess district<br />

(CBD) and possibly a few other major activity centers, primarily as a result of market<br />

forces that establish a strong premium on land costs. Outside of these areas, park<strong>in</strong>g<br />

supply is generally plentiful, due to long-established plann<strong>in</strong>g and zon<strong>in</strong>g regulations that<br />

require developers to provide ample park<strong>in</strong>g, and free (Shoup, 2005). However, some<br />

cities, such as Charlotte, Portland, Oregon, and Pasadena, have taken steps to reduce<br />

park<strong>in</strong>g supply <strong>in</strong> transit-oriented developments or other urban neighborhoods. Active<br />

management of park<strong>in</strong>g pric<strong>in</strong>g to regulate demand is be<strong>in</strong>g tested <strong>in</strong> New York and<br />

Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C. and considered <strong>in</strong> other cities <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g Chicago, Los Angeles, and San<br />

Francisco (Nguyen, 2009). Park<strong>in</strong>g cash-out and worksite park<strong>in</strong>g pric<strong>in</strong>g can be<br />

implemented by employers or property managers, and are considered a subset of<br />

employer commute measures (Section 5.5) <strong>in</strong> this report.<br />

Magnitude and Tim<strong>in</strong>g of GHG Reductions<br />

Both the cost and supply of park<strong>in</strong>g are significant determ<strong>in</strong>ants of travel behavior. (These<br />

factors tend to be closely related, as park<strong>in</strong>g tends to be priced when – and only when – its<br />

availability is limited.) Most studies of park<strong>in</strong>g pric<strong>in</strong>g have focused on commut<strong>in</strong>g<br />

behavior. Cervero (1993) found that rail transit mode shares <strong>in</strong> the San Francisco Bay Area<br />

<strong>in</strong>creased by about 50 percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts (e.g., 64 versus 14 percent transit mode share) if<br />

the employee had to pay for park<strong>in</strong>g, compared to those that were given free park<strong>in</strong>g. A<br />

study of employers <strong>in</strong> California found that park<strong>in</strong>g cash-out programs reduced vehicle<br />

trips an average of 11 percent (Shoup, 1997).<br />

Information on the potential nationwide GHG reductions from park<strong>in</strong>g pric<strong>in</strong>g or other<br />

park<strong>in</strong>g management strategies is very limited. Two recent estimates have focused on<br />

commute travel <strong>in</strong> particular. Nationwide, only 5 percent of employees pay for park<strong>in</strong>g,<br />

so <strong>in</strong> theory there is great potential for expand<strong>in</strong>g the scope of worksite-based park<strong>in</strong>g<br />

pric<strong>in</strong>g. On the other hand, market prices for park<strong>in</strong>g usually exist only <strong>in</strong> CBDs and other<br />

densely built activity centers, and, accord<strong>in</strong>g to data from the 2000 U.S. Census, less than<br />

10 percent of a typical metropolitan area’s workforce is located <strong>in</strong> the CBD. Assum<strong>in</strong>g that<br />

an additional 5 percent of workers nationwide could have park<strong>in</strong>g priced at market rates,<br />

reduc<strong>in</strong>g SOV use per worker by 20 percent, and further assum<strong>in</strong>g that work trips make<br />

up 30 percent of total VMT, the total reduction <strong>in</strong> VMT on a nationwide basis would be<br />

approximately 0.3 percent (EEA, 2008). This represents a reduction of 3.5 mmt CO2e <strong>in</strong><br />

2030. A nationwide fee of $5 daily per park<strong>in</strong>g space levied on all worker-utilized park<strong>in</strong>g<br />

spaces (or the equivalent, such as a $5 cash-out <strong>in</strong>centive offered to all workers who choose<br />

not to drive) is estimated to reduce emissions much more substantially—by nearly 40 mmt<br />

CO2e <strong>in</strong> 2030 (Cambridge Systematics, 2009). However, it is not clear how such a broadbased<br />

fee would be implemented or enforced.<br />

Some park<strong>in</strong>g management strategies, such as market-rate pric<strong>in</strong>g of on-street spaces or<br />

offer<strong>in</strong>g a cash-out option to employees, can be implemented with<strong>in</strong> one or two years.<br />

However, others (such as reduc<strong>in</strong>g park<strong>in</strong>g requirements <strong>in</strong> zon<strong>in</strong>g) take many years to<br />

5-71

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!