03.07.2013 Views

TURKOMANS BETWEEN TWO EMPIRES: THE ... - Bilkent University

TURKOMANS BETWEEN TWO EMPIRES: THE ... - Bilkent University

TURKOMANS BETWEEN TWO EMPIRES: THE ... - Bilkent University

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

in tribal or sub-tribal societies because of two major reasons that reinforce intra-tribal<br />

cohesion: one pertains to economic base and the other comes from the very nature of<br />

nomadic mode of life. In terms of economy, the fundamental productive base of<br />

nomadic society is formed by a pastoral mode of subsistence, in which the ownership<br />

relations are quite different from that of sedentary societies. The economic relations in<br />

nomadic societies are based on two important foundations: private ownership of<br />

livestock and corporate ownership of pastures. 139 So, above all, corporate ownership of<br />

pastures forces nomads to act and behave collectively. 140 Although every family has its<br />

own properties, such as herd, tent, several tools etc., it is not sufficient to stand alone. As<br />

Roger Cribb has made the point clear, though being autonomous in terms of decision<br />

making and disposal of some sources, “pastoral household can not stand alone.” 141 It<br />

needs other households to fulfill the full economic cycle and migratory operations. Thus<br />

communal ties are more advanced with regard to sedentary societies. And these<br />

communal ties usually, if not always, are based on kinship and affinality. 142<br />

In addition to economic constraints, the very nature of nomadic life also forces<br />

individuals to knit to one another - at the first stage between the members of family and<br />

139 Barth observed in the Basseri case that the pasturelands of each tira and oulads, that are intermediary<br />

sub-tribal units, are assigned by the chief. A member of oulad has by birth the right of grazing on the<br />

pastures of his oulad without any limitation. The movements of man is restricted by the limits of oulad or<br />

section with whom he shared inherited pasturelands. But in the limits of pastureland of oulad he is totally<br />

free to move from one camp to other. See Barth, Nomads of South Persia, pp. 54-60. For a broader<br />

analysis of ownership relations in nomadic societies see Khazanov, Nomads and the Outside World, pp.<br />

123-25.<br />

140 For an analysis of ‘collective behavior’ see Dennis Brissett, “Collective Behavior: The Sense of<br />

Rubric”, The American Journal of Sociology, vol. 74, no.1, 1968, pp. 70-78.<br />

141 Roger Cribb, Nomads in Archaeology, Cambridge: Cambridge <strong>University</strong> Press, 1991, p. 39.<br />

142 Furthermore, nomadic families are relatively small and that the workforce required by the household is<br />

not only insufficient for the labor, but is subject to seasonal variations as well. As a rule, Khazanov says, it<br />

is impossible, or at least very difficult, for one nomadic household of average prosperity to accomplish a<br />

complete productive cycle on its own. Thus cooperation within a group by families is necessary.<br />

Consequently, economic structure endorses, or arguably enforces, social solidarity and collective actions<br />

in nomadic communities. See Khazanov, Nomads and the Outside World, pp. 130-31.<br />

52

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!