27.06.2013 Views

Proceedings of the 3rd European Conference on Intellectual Capital

Proceedings of the 3rd European Conference on Intellectual Capital

Proceedings of the 3rd European Conference on Intellectual Capital

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

B<strong>on</strong>gani Ngwenya<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g>se arguments, previous empirical studies (DeCarolis and Deeds, 1999; D` Este, 2005; Geroski,<br />

Machin, and Van Reenen, 1993; Roberts and Amit, 2003) have generally dem<strong>on</strong>strated that<br />

variati<strong>on</strong>s am<strong>on</strong>g firms in <str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g>ir rates <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> accumulating new knowledge, and in <str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g>ir stocks <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> innovative<br />

knowledge assets, c<strong>on</strong>tribute to differences in <str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g> financial performance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g>se firms in <str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g>ir<br />

different industries. For example, using a sample <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> United States <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> America biotechnology firms,<br />

DeCarolis and Deeds (1999) found that both stocks and flows <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> organizati<strong>on</strong>al knowledge had a<br />

positive impact <strong>on</strong> firm performance. Research has shown similar positive effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> innovative inputs<br />

and outputs <strong>on</strong> performance in various o<str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g>r geographical and industrial settings, such as Australian<br />

retail banking (Roberts and Amit, 2003), Spanish pharmaceuticals (D` Este, 2005), and United<br />

Kingdom manufacturing (Geroski et al., 1993).This paper argues that, like Total Quality Management<br />

(TQM) practices, Openness in eGovernment, and o<str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g>r organizati<strong>on</strong>al practices, strategic innovati<strong>on</strong><br />

and knowledge management is an organizati<strong>on</strong>al practice that can also be explained and viewed from<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g> instituti<strong>on</strong>al <str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory’s account <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> diffusi<strong>on</strong>, adopti<strong>on</strong> and implementati<strong>on</strong>. Diffusi<strong>on</strong> occurs when<br />

new products and services begin flowing deeper within <str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g>ir initial markets, or to areas different from<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong>e in which <str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g>y were originally introduced (Ruggles and Little, 1997).The c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>al diffusi<strong>on</strong><br />

model mostly neglects practice implementati<strong>on</strong>, yet several studies have called for viewing diffusi<strong>on</strong><br />

practices as dynamic (Rogers, 1978; Strang and Soule, 1998) and thus for studying <str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g> details <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

implementati<strong>on</strong> (Edelman, 1992; Fiss and Zajac, 2006; Westphal and Zajac, 2001; Zbaracki, 1998).<br />

The questi<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> why and how organizati<strong>on</strong>s adopt new practices have remained a central topic in <str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

management and organizati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory literatures (Abrahams<strong>on</strong>, 1991; Davis & Greve, 1997; Palmer,<br />

Jennings, & Zhou, 1993; Westphal, Gulati, & Shortell, 1997). Prior research has <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fered a number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

important insights into diffusi<strong>on</strong> processes am<strong>on</strong>g populati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> organizati<strong>on</strong>s, ranging from <str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g> role<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> organizati<strong>on</strong> size and market power (Geroski, 2000; Hannan & McDowell, 1984) to <str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g> importance<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> imitati<strong>on</strong> processes (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983) and trendsetters (Abrahams<strong>on</strong>, 1996). Two distinct<br />

approaches to explaining adopti<strong>on</strong> motivati<strong>on</strong> have characterized much <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this literature <strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

diffusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> practices and administrative technologies (Strang & Macy, 2001). The first approach is<br />

rooted in <str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omic literature, building <strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g> rati<strong>on</strong>al actor model, in which organizati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

adopti<strong>on</strong> is motivated by a desire for technical or efficiency gains and related boosts to ec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

performance (Katz & Shapiro, 1987; Teece, 1980). The sec<strong>on</strong>d approach represents a more<br />

sociological perspective, emphasizing <str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g> social embeddedness <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> organizati<strong>on</strong>s and motivati<strong>on</strong>s that<br />

stem primarily from a desire to appear legitimate to powerful c<strong>on</strong>stituents, peer organizati<strong>on</strong>s, or<br />

outside stakeholders (Abrahams<strong>on</strong>, 1991; DiMaggio & Powell, 1983).<br />

Perhaps <str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g> most important integrati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> insights from both sets <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> explanati<strong>on</strong>s is Tolbert &<br />

Zucker`s (1983) two-stage model, according to which early adopters seek technical gains from<br />

adopti<strong>on</strong>, but later adopters are primarily interested in <str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g> social benefits <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> appearing legitimate.<br />

Tolbert & Zucker c<strong>on</strong>sequently argued that <str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g>se later adopters implemented reforms primarily out <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

a desire to appear legitimate. Similarly, in <str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g>ir study <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> United States hospitals, Westphal, Gulati, &<br />

Shortell (1997) suggest that early adopters <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Total Quality Management (TQM) practices were<br />

motivated by efficiency c<strong>on</strong>cerns. However as TQM practices became instituti<strong>on</strong>alized and thus<br />

became expected elements <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> organizati<strong>on</strong>, <str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g> logic <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> evaluati<strong>on</strong> shifted, and later adopters were<br />

motivated primarily by legitimacy c<strong>on</strong>cerns ra<str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g>r than efficiency gains.<br />

In this paper, developed technologies and ec<strong>on</strong>omies, like US, UK, China and Japan that are str<strong>on</strong>g<br />

in innovati<strong>on</strong> and knowledge management are c<strong>on</strong>sidered as early adopters <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> strategic innovati<strong>on</strong><br />

and knowledge management practices, while emerging technologies and ec<strong>on</strong>omies like Zimbabwe<br />

are viewed as later adopters <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g> practices. According to <str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g> instituti<strong>on</strong>al <str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory’s account <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

diffusi<strong>on</strong> early adopters <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g>se practices are motivated by, and seeking technical gains from<br />

adopti<strong>on</strong>, but later adopters are primarily interested in <str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g> social benefits <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> appearing legitimate, to<br />

realize organizati<strong>on</strong>al creativity and organizati<strong>on</strong>al development.<br />

Although this two-stage model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> diffusi<strong>on</strong> has been a touchst<strong>on</strong>e for many studies that apply<br />

instituti<strong>on</strong>al <str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory to practice diffusi<strong>on</strong> (Bar<strong>on</strong>, Dobbin, & Jennings, 1986; Meyer, Stephens<strong>on</strong>, &<br />

Webster, 1985; Pangarkar & Klein, 1998; Scott, 1995; Westphal & Zajac, 1994), it has recently drawn<br />

critical attenti<strong>on</strong>. For example, Lounsbury (2007) argued that segregating ec<strong>on</strong>omic and social logics<br />

is problematic, since <str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g> distincti<strong>on</strong> between technical and social benefits is itself embedded in<br />

instituti<strong>on</strong>s (Lounsbury, 2002; Thornt<strong>on</strong>, 2004). By implicati<strong>on</strong>, technical and social motivati<strong>on</strong>s are<br />

less disjointed than previously <str<strong>on</strong>g>the</str<strong>on</strong>g>orized (Schneiberg & Soule, 2005; Scott, Ruef, Mendel, & Car<strong>on</strong>na,<br />

2000).<br />

315

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!