13.02.2013 Views

Preproceedings 2006 - Austrian Ludwig Wittgenstein Society

Preproceedings 2006 - Austrian Ludwig Wittgenstein Society

Preproceedings 2006 - Austrian Ludwig Wittgenstein Society

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

An economist’s reflections on some recent trends in European culture. - Y.S. Brenner<br />

several important services can hardly be improved by<br />

labour-time-reducing innovations considering that they<br />

require the simultaneous attendance of consumer and<br />

provider, and because their quality depends on duration,<br />

for example patients and doctors and pupils and teachers.<br />

This, again, appeared to confirm the metaphysical<br />

foundation of economic theory. An "invisible hand" was<br />

leading the economy toward full employment equilibrium. It<br />

was an illusion. In fact, old and new monopolistic practices<br />

prevented prices from falling in line with labour input, and<br />

many services, which were expected to provide the new<br />

employment opportunities, fell prey to automatization.<br />

Together with this, the cost of the services where labourtime<br />

could not be reduced, greatly increased in<br />

comparison with the cost of the goods where new<br />

technologies could be applied. Obviously, if two cars can<br />

be produced with the labour input previously required to<br />

produce one car, and the time required by a hairdresser to<br />

serve a customer remains as before, then, compared to<br />

the cost of a car, a haircut becomes expensive. The<br />

problem with this was that the relative rising cost<br />

happened mainly in the state funded services. 15<br />

In other words, relative to the decreasing costs of goods<br />

produced by the private sector, the services provided by<br />

the public sector became dearer. This was one reason for<br />

the rising cost of the Welfare State but not the only reason<br />

for the relatively high taxes and the growing public debt.<br />

Equally important were the profound changes in the<br />

lifestyle of the increasingly more affluent societies, and the<br />

increasing complexity of the economic system. The<br />

widespread ideological commitment to greater social and<br />

economic equity placed with the state many of the<br />

obligations which traditionally rested with the family. The<br />

customary responsibility for the aged, and for healthcare<br />

and education, shifted from the household to the public<br />

sphere. But people accustomed to assigning social status<br />

to private ownership of property tend to forget that even if<br />

these needs were met by the family rather than the state<br />

the share of the national income allocated to their<br />

satisfaction would still be high and rising. The aged and<br />

infirm would still have to be housed and fed; medical care<br />

would still have to be paid for, teachers would still want to<br />

be remunerated. In this respect, the difference between a<br />

regulated and deregulated economy is inconsequential,<br />

but the distribution of the burden is significantly different.<br />

Under a system of progressive taxation, the rich, while<br />

being the least dependent on its services, are obliged to<br />

pay more than the poor to maintain the provisions of the<br />

Welfare State. This then, is the crux of the matter. The rich<br />

are allergic to subsidizing the "undeserving poor".<br />

In practice, although everyone was entitled to free<br />

healthcare, state pensions; free education including higher<br />

education, unemployment benefit, and many other<br />

advantages, it was the large middle class which gained<br />

most from the State. It had better access than the poorer<br />

members of society to advantages provided by the state. 16<br />

Yet, the cultural legacy of old-style capitalism prevented<br />

the majority of the members of this class from recognizing<br />

this. Their eyes were focussed on taxes and other<br />

deductions from their incomes and not on the advantages<br />

they got in return.<br />

Next to this, government became more costly<br />

because the economic system became more complex and<br />

more prone to monopolistic influences. It had to finance<br />

the construction and maintenance of new national<br />

communication networks (which at least initially were too<br />

expensive to be constructed and maintained by private<br />

enterprise alone), new sources of energy, new means of<br />

protecting the public from epidemic diseases, from<br />

pollution of air and water, and, in the shadow of the Cold<br />

War and later threats, new expensive investments in<br />

defence related goods and services.<br />

The power of monster conglomerates 17 , and their<br />

power to influence prices, is well known and needs here<br />

no elaboration But while there was little new in the<br />

tendency toward monopoly, the stimulus it received in the<br />

1980s from technological developments ushered in a new<br />

market structure. Manufacturing production-technology,<br />

and Computer Integrated Manufacturing (CIM), together<br />

with changes in the world economy, caused a revision of<br />

large corporations' market strategy. 18 From being<br />

companies in many countries, important multinationals<br />

became global concerns. 19<br />

This new market structure rested on the presence of near<br />

monopoly in certain semi-finished goods and particular<br />

production processes. Each new investment in any of<br />

these industries led to a greater output than an equivalent<br />

investment did before, while the oligopolistic structures<br />

prevented prices from falling. Consequently consumer<br />

demand did not increase in line with rising productivity,<br />

and profits could no longer be made in the market-place.<br />

The result was that producers turned to process innovation<br />

because in a sluggish or shrinking market the way to<br />

preserve or increase profitability is to reduce production<br />

costs. With this, competition shifted from markets to<br />

innovation. The most efficient process innovator made the<br />

highest profit. As process innovation (as well as product<br />

innovation) usually involves high R&D expenditure and<br />

costly new equipment, the new structure strengthened the<br />

near monopoly of successful producers. It facilitated the<br />

determination of prices in line with investment plans with<br />

little regard for market competition. Variations in the<br />

volume of demand did not influence prices but determined<br />

the volume of production. The final outcome was growing<br />

unemployment together with rising prices and rising rates<br />

of interest. This then, was the phenomenon known as<br />

stagflation. 20 In short, the market-mechanism of prices did<br />

no longer function in the way it did before, or in the way<br />

the pre-Keynesians expected it to function.<br />

What the situation really required was a judicious<br />

allocation of the fruits of the technologically generated<br />

economic growth. Such an allocation of added value does<br />

not imply less for the rich, but more for the poor and a little<br />

less more for the rich. In other words, what was needed<br />

was state intervention to sustain effective demand in line<br />

with growing productivity, and measures to provide<br />

sufficient capital to allow innovative investment to<br />

continue. With stringent steps to reduce abuse of social<br />

security, to restrain tax evasion and to restrict the ill-use of<br />

public funds, this could probably have been achieved with<br />

little or no inflation. But, since the mid-1970s, instead of<br />

doing this, governments adopted economic policies<br />

designed to stop inflation by wage restraint and by<br />

stimulating the private sector. 21 Governments<br />

featherbedded the rich in the hope that easy money will<br />

encourage investment and revitalize demand for labour.<br />

The result was that investment continued to increase, but<br />

only in process innovation – in the replacement of human<br />

labour by machines, and production was scaled down in<br />

line with the resulting diminishing consumers' effective<br />

demand, thus increasing unemployment. 22 Eventually,<br />

after the collapse of the Soviet Union, an entirely new<br />

economic structure was gradually developing in Western<br />

Europe with investment moving to the East and labour<br />

from the East into Western Europe. 23<br />

55

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!