30.08.2014 Views

ASi" kUCTURE FlOR DEVELOPMENT

ASi" kUCTURE FlOR DEVELOPMENT

ASi" kUCTURE FlOR DEVELOPMENT

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

percent to 53 percent in 1993, and in revenue coliec- Thiis effect has been demonstrated most convinction<br />

from less than 50 percent to 91 percent of ingly for water, where the concerns for the poor are<br />

billings.<br />

properly strong. In the Brazilian city of Grande Vito-<br />

One aspect of cost recovery that separates good ria, Espirito Santo state, the wilLingness to pay for<br />

perfonners from poorer ones is that good perform- new water connections in 1993 was four times the<br />

ers recover the costs of maintaining suffcient capac- cost of providing the service, while the willingness<br />

ity to meet peak demand by levying a charge based to pay for. sewage collection and treatment was 2.3<br />

on potential demand or actual consumption at peak. times its cost. Without treatment before disposal, the<br />

This method helps avoid power outages and water willingness to pay falls to only 1A times the cost beshortages.<br />

In other words, good performers are cause untreated sewage creates health problems and<br />

much more careful than others in assessing de- reduces the recreational value (mostly the fishing<br />

mand. In Colombia, India, and Korea, this capacity yield) of the waters into which it is discharged.<br />

cost is charged only to the largest commercial and The willingness to pay for water is high for good<br />

industrial users because they tend to be the main reason; For the poor, easier access to water can free<br />

source of peak demand.<br />

up time that can be used to pursue income-earning<br />

Just as important as the incentive to meet objec- activities. In rural Pakistan, women with access to<br />

tives negotiated with the government is the finan- improved water supply spend nearly 1.5 fewer<br />

cial independence that allows public managers to hours a day fetching water than do women without<br />

rely on the price system to assess users' willingness this access- Such savings are reflected in the value<br />

to pay. Reliance on the price mechanism is in the in- users attach to the services. In Haiti a household's<br />

terest of users because it directs provision toward willingness to pay for a new private connection inpreferences<br />

determined by users rather than bu- creases by as much as 40 percent if the current water<br />

reaucrats. Users are wiling or able to pay more source is at least a kilometer away<br />

often than they are given credit for (Chapter 4).<br />

The poor are not simply willing to pay in theory-<br />

What keeps so many public utilities from recov- they are paying in practice During the rnid-1970s to<br />

ering costs is political constraints Low prices are the early 1980s, people in seventeen cities surveyed<br />

popular among those who receive a service even if were paying private water vendors an average of<br />

they are willing to pay more. In Bangladesh, In- twenty-five times the prices charged by the utility.<br />

donesia, Pakistan, and the Philippines, receipts from In Nouakchott, Mauritania, and Port-au-Prince,<br />

irrigation user fees are 20 to 90 percent less than the Haiti, vendors were charging up to a hundred times<br />

cost of operation and maintenance. This shortfall re- the public utllity price. Expanding the public utility<br />

flects the strength of the farmers' lobbies and their network to give the poor access would mean that<br />

ability to get political endorsement for high subsi- fthey would pay less than they are now willig and<br />

dies. Moreover, with subsidies guaranteed, public able to pay private providers.<br />

managers have little incentive to perform well or to<br />

improve their responsiveness to users. Without po- Public wuorks and financial autononmy<br />

litical support, the needed organizational changessuch<br />

as linking managers' rewards to the financial Making public works agencies financially indepenperformance<br />

of the department or utlity-will not dent does not mean that the public organization<br />

suffice.<br />

collects revenue directly from users to cover its operational<br />

costs. For public works, it is difficult or im-<br />

COST RECOVERY AND THE PooRi Many govern- possible to measure-and hence to price-individinents<br />

fear that fully recovering costs will hurt the ual use. Nevertheless, a predictable and transparent<br />

poor, yet increasing prices to enable cost recovery in flow of revenue is necessary, based on user fees and<br />

the delivery of services may actually help the poor. standard budgetary allocations from govemnment.<br />

They often pay much higher prices per unit for pri- To some extent, the goal is one of financial accountvately<br />

provided water and lighting because they are ability rather than financial autonomy because the<br />

not connected to public service networks that have main objective is to achieve predictable and adelower<br />

unit costs, and because they do not benefit quate financing. The key to the success of Korea's<br />

from subsidies to users of the public system-usu- highway corporation has been making the perforally<br />

the better-off. Expansion of access benefits the mance of the organization more transparent (a<br />

poor by allowing them to rely on less costly sources process described in Box 2.4) and lining budgetary<br />

of water and power. (Cases in which subsidies are transfers to performance. But in many developing<br />

needed are discussed in Chapter 4.)<br />

countries the budgetary process does not allow for<br />

49

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!