30.08.2014 Views

ASi" kUCTURE FlOR DEVELOPMENT

ASi" kUCTURE FlOR DEVELOPMENT

ASi" kUCTURE FlOR DEVELOPMENT

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

private management can become complacent about tance phone services, price caps on the dominant<br />

making the right investments and keeping costs provider, AT&T, are thought to be the only instrudown.<br />

ment needed because profits are limited by compet-<br />

The response-has been to design new "incentive" ing suppliers. But where local monopolies exist (as<br />

regulations in which the prices a provider is al- in local telephone services), rate-of-return considerlowed<br />

to charge do not hinge on costs incurred. ations can reassert themselves so that, over time,<br />

Thus, if costs increase, profits are lowered; if costs price-cap regimes may converge toward their ratedecline,<br />

the provider and investors enjoy greater of-retum predecessors. Nonetheless, price caps do<br />

profits. Incentive regulation therefore seeks to moti- have the advantage of shifting a greater part of the<br />

vate providers to use their superior knowledge of financial risk onto providers of infrastructure seroperating<br />

conditions to lower costs and introduce vices, who cannot be sure that the regulator will<br />

new services.<br />

allow them to recoup excess costs. This threat en-<br />

Price caps. An example of incentive regulation is courages tighter self-monitoring of performance.<br />

the increasingly popular price-cap, or "RPI-X," Yadstick conmpetition. When direct competition or<br />

method for determining permitted increases in ser- competition from producers of substitute products<br />

vice price. RPI is the percentage increase in the retail will not work, competitive forces can be replicated<br />

price index (other indexes of costs that the provider through comparisons with performance elsewhere.<br />

does not control can also be used), and X is the (pre- A utility in one region can be motivated to perform<br />

determined) expected percentage increase in the better by promises of greater rewards if its perforprovider's<br />

productivity- The infrastructure provider mance exceeds that of a similar utility in another rehas<br />

an incentive to lower costs, since gains in pro- gion. However, only if the utilities' input prices,<br />

ductivity greater than the expected X percent con- market demand, and government regulations<br />

tribute to increased profits. To maintain intcentives equate can better performance be attnbuted to the<br />

for efficient production, the X-factor should remain efforts of the utility.<br />

unchanged for a period of several years.<br />

A number of countries use yardstick competi-<br />

Price caps are diffusing widely to different tion, fornally or infonrnally. In France the contracts<br />

countries and, gradually, to sectors other than of the local water company often depend on the<br />

telecommunications, where they originated. The quality of services and their production costs rela-<br />

United Kingdom has led the way, using pnce caps tive to those of other French water companies. The<br />

in airports, telecommumications, electricity distri- water sector regulator in the United Kingdom relies<br />

bution, gas, and water supplv. Elsewhere, how- explicitly on cost comparisons. The Chilean teleever,<br />

their main application has been in telecom- communications industry uses an important vanant<br />

munications, with electricity distribution a distant of yardstick competition. A hypothetical "efficient"<br />

second. In Mexico, for example, the government firn, rather than other Chilean finns, is used in setintroduced<br />

price-cap regulation for Telmex in Jan- ting the prices that telecommunications suppliers<br />

uary 1992 which applies a price cap to the overall can charge. International cost and price trends are<br />

weighted average priee of Telmex's services, rather used to estimate the performance an efficient firm<br />

than a specific pnce cap for each service. In the should achieve, and prices are established based on<br />

United States many state regulatory commissions this estimate. Within this framework, the more effihave<br />

shifted from rate-of-return to price-ap regu- cient the Chilean firm, the larger its financial relation.<br />

Where comparison is possible, as between wards. In electric power, reasonable distribution<br />

different states in the United States, the evidence is costs are estimated for three "reference systems,"<br />

that price caps lead to lower prices than does rate- which vary according to such key determinants as<br />

of-return regulation.<br />

distribution costs, population density, and peak de-<br />

There are also some enirly indications that the dif-- mand. Individual electricity distributors are placed<br />

ference between price-cap and rate-of-return regula- in one of these three systems, and delivery prices<br />

tion may not be as great as originally tlhought Price are regulated accordingly. A distributor benefits if it<br />

caps are rardy observed in their pure form. Most delivers electricity more cheaply than the average<br />

rgulators see a continued need to assess the rate of provider in its reference system. However, manipureturn<br />

and so set the caps on estimaftcs of profitabil- lation of "reference system' costs by the few suppliity,<br />

once again increasing the information require- ers in the market has driven the government to exmeits<br />

for effective regulation. An exception arises plore improvements in its use of benchmarks.<br />

when profits are under the control of competitive Although yardstick competition is limited by the<br />

forces. For example, in the U.S. market for long dis- need for sufficiently refined and comparable infor-<br />

50:

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!