14.12.2012 Views

2005 - 2006 - Pinsent Masons Water Yearbook 2012

2005 - 2006 - Pinsent Masons Water Yearbook 2012

2005 - 2006 - Pinsent Masons Water Yearbook 2012

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

PART 4: APPENDIX 2: PRIVATE SECTOR PARTICIPATION<br />

services such as meter installation. Santiago’s EMOS is the most notable example, having been<br />

commercialised in 1989 and sold in 1999. Other examples include a number of German cities<br />

(e.g. Hamburg), South Africa’s Umgeni <strong>Water</strong> and Thailand’s municipal and provincial water<br />

authorities.<br />

A hybrid privatisation has emerged from a number of these commercial entities where the<br />

municipality floats some of the shares of the entity, while retaining majority ownership and<br />

therefore management control. The best example is in Brazil, where Rio’s SABESP is actively<br />

traded on the national Bourse, while the municipality for the time being retains 72% of the<br />

company’s equity. 49% of Belgium’s Aquafin has been sold to a number of corporate and<br />

institutional investors, with overall control being retained by MVW, the region’s sewerage<br />

management agency.<br />

O&M and lease contracts<br />

The next step up involves awarding O&M or lease contracts. Operations & maintenance (O&M)<br />

contracts usually operate on a fixed fee basis. Lease contracts typically involve asset operation<br />

and tariffs, but not capital expenditure. These two types of contract do not delegate full financial<br />

responsibility to the private operator, especially with regards to private capital investments.<br />

Concessions<br />

Concessions involve the private sector operation of assets in order to pay for new facilities and<br />

upgrading work. Build-Own-Operate (BOO) and Build-Operate-Transfer (BOT) contracts sell<br />

specific services to the municipality in relation to a specific programme of capital improvements,<br />

while the full utility concession contract embraces all aspects of service provision and capital<br />

spending. These contracts require a much more specific regulatory environment so as to<br />

account for the elements of risk involved. Other varieties sometimes seen are BOTT (build,<br />

operate, train and transfer) and DFBOT (design, finance, build, operate and transfer) contracts.<br />

A BOO/BOT project’s cash flow is usually contractually pre-determined, often with government<br />

backing. There is an element of construction risk, but the absence of market risk means that the<br />

project can have more debt loaded in than in a full utility privatisation. A project’s construction<br />

risk can be mitigated whereby a facility already generating cash flow gets taken over for<br />

expansion by the private sector. Therefore, BOT/BOO projects are an effective means of rapidly<br />

organising private capital and management towards a narrow range of services. However, some<br />

of the simpler project-oriented contracts do not affect the utility’s management and operation,<br />

thus underlying problems such as leakage (and illegal interception), over-staffing and poor tariff<br />

collection may not be addressed. In these cases, the underlying utility remains uncreditworthy,<br />

and it can be argued that a BOO/BOT contract may therefore in fact delay system-wide<br />

improvements.<br />

In full utility concessions, existing revenues can be used immediately to service debt, thereby<br />

mitigating construction risk. Over a period of time, a utility can benefit from a steady flow of<br />

revenues from a diversified customer base and, if it integrates horizontally, from a diversified<br />

asset base. A more robust balance sheet can be created, allowing for internal finance as well as<br />

the use of capital markets to sell long term debt.<br />

Asset sale<br />

The most dramatic and politically contentious form of privatisation is the outright sale of the<br />

utility’s assets. To date this has been used in the 1989 sale of the English and Welsh water and<br />

sewage companies (WASCs), in two examples in the Czech Republic, in one in Belize and in<br />

Chile. While the assets are in private hands, the licence to operate them can be subject to<br />

renewal. In the case of the UK WASCs, a 30 year operating licence was awarded to each entity<br />

in 1989. It is evident that the assets carry no value unless one can operate them, while the cost<br />

of building a duplicate network would be prohibitive.<br />

The problem with losing stakeholder participation in utility services is that it can erode the<br />

customers’ sense of civic duty. During the 1976 drought, water consumption in England and<br />

376 <strong>Pinsent</strong> <strong>Masons</strong> <strong>Water</strong> <strong>Yearbook</strong> <strong>2005</strong>-<strong>2006</strong>

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!