11.07.2015 Views

The Bourgeois Virtues: Ethics for an Age of Commerce

The Bourgeois Virtues: Ethics for an Age of Commerce

The Bourgeois Virtues: Ethics for an Age of Commerce

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

good barons 489hum<strong>an</strong> computers rushing about calculating what economists are pleasedto call “marginal utility.” Early in the resist<strong>an</strong>ce to a new <strong>an</strong>d precisely mathematicalexpression <strong>of</strong> a Benthamite Max U, Thorstein Veblen, I have noted,attacked the notion that people were “lightning calculators.” But such precisionis not necessary to get the more import<strong>an</strong>t results <strong>of</strong> economics, <strong>an</strong>dVeblen’s criticism falls flat. This could be proven easily with our massivecomputing capacity nowadays. If you were to simulate a toy economy <strong>of</strong>1,000 consumers <strong>an</strong>d producers, you would find that even approximatemaximizing would put the economy very near to where it would be withsuper rationality.Interpreting a broad, contextual, rhetorical prudence as the same thing asa narrow, rationalist, first-order predicate logic <strong>of</strong> “rationality” has alwaysbeen a mistake. Plato committed it. Modern economists commit it with gusto.<strong>The</strong>ir allies in sociobiology <strong>an</strong>d evolutionary psychology delight in it. In areview <strong>of</strong> a book by one <strong>of</strong> the present-day committers <strong>of</strong> the mistake, StevenPinker, the philosopher Jerry Fodor notes that “as far as <strong>an</strong>yone knows, relev<strong>an</strong>ce,strength, simplicity, centrality <strong>an</strong>d the like are properties, not <strong>of</strong> singlesentences, but <strong>of</strong> whole belief systems; <strong>an</strong>d there’s no reason at all to supposethat such global properties <strong>of</strong> belief systems are syntactic. In my view, the cognitivescience that we’ve got so far has hardly begun to face this issue.” 2 Relev<strong>an</strong>ce,strength, simplicity, <strong>an</strong>d so <strong>for</strong>th are there<strong>for</strong>e not reducible to a Turingmachine. That is, they are not the <strong>for</strong>mal inferences <strong>of</strong> the rational theory <strong>of</strong>mind, such as that “all bachelors are men; John is a bachelor; there<strong>for</strong>e [triumph<strong>an</strong>tlyconcluded, in case we hadn’t already noticed it] John is a m<strong>an</strong>.”<strong>The</strong> same could be said <strong>of</strong> metaphor, irony, narrative, jokes. <strong>The</strong>y are localproperties <strong>of</strong> whole belief systems, not <strong>of</strong> single sentences.Allocation <strong>of</strong> goods to the use <strong>of</strong> the highest value is one result <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it. <strong>The</strong>other is invention, which in a larger view is just <strong>an</strong>other <strong>for</strong>m <strong>of</strong> alertness inbuying (ideas) low <strong>an</strong>d selling high. <strong>The</strong> Americ<strong>an</strong> economy in the late nineteenthcentury was a deal-making, inventive place, with secure private property<strong>an</strong>d reasonably honest courts in which deals could be repaired whenthings went wrong, <strong>an</strong>d a society that accorded work very high prestige.National product per head there<strong>for</strong>e went up smartly 1870–1900, slower th<strong>an</strong>it did in the 1990s, <strong>for</strong> example, but very respectably <strong>for</strong> the time. If you lookinto the way Carnegie <strong>an</strong>d Rockefeller actually got their <strong>for</strong>tunes, it turns out

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!