02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

PRICE ($)

1.25

1.00

0.75

0.50

0.25

0

Figure 3.13

D

5

Market

demand

curve

B

E 0

Market

supply

curve

10 15 20 25 30 35

QUANTITY OF CANDY BARS (MILLIONS)

SUPPLY AND DEMAND EQUILIBRIUM

Equilibrium occurs at the intersection of the demand and

supply curves, at point E 0 . At any price above E 0 , the quantity

supplied will exceed the quantity demanded, the market will be

out of equilibrium, and there will be excess supply. At any price

below E 0 , the quantity demanded will exceed the quantity supplied,

the market will be out of equilibrium, and there will be

excess demand.

C

A

it up. When the weight is at rest, it is in equilibrium, with the two

forces just offsetting each other. If someone pulls the weight down

a little bit, the force of the spring will be greater than the force

of gravity, and the weight will spring up. In the absence of any

further interventions, the weight will bob back and forth and

eventually return to its equilibrium position.

An economic equilibrium is established in the same way. At

the equilibrium price, consumers get precisely the quantity of

the good they are willing to buy at that price, and producers sell

precisely the quantity they are willing to sell at that price. The

market clears. To emphasize this condition, economists sometimes

refer to the equilibrium price as the market clearing

price. In equilibrium, neither producers nor consumers have

any incentive to change.

But consider the price of $1.00 in Figure 3.13. There is no

equilibrium quantity here. First find $1.00 on the vertical axis.

Now look across to find point A on the supply curve, and read

down to the horizontal axis; point A tells you that a price of

$1.00, firms want to supply 34 million candy bars. Now look at

point B on the demand curve. Point B shows that at a price of

$1.00 consumers want to buy only 13 million candy bars. Like

the weight bobbing on a spring however, this market will work

its way back to equilibrium in the following way. At a price of

$1.00, there is excess supply. As producers discover that they

cannot sell as much as they would like at this price, some of

them will lower their prices slightly, hoping to take business from other producers.

When one producer lowers prices, his competitors will have to respond, for fear

that they will end up unable to sell their goods. As prices come down, consumers

will also buy more, and so on until the market reaches the equilibrium price

and quantity.

Similarly, assume that the price is lower than $0.75, say $0.50. At the lower price,

there is excess demand: individuals want to buy 30 million candy bars (point C),

while firms want to produce only 5 million (point D). Consumers unable to purchase

all they want will offer to pay a bit more; other consumers, afraid of having to do

without, will match these higher bids or exceed them. As prices start to increase,

suppliers will also have a greater incentive to produce more. Again the market will

tend toward the equilibrium point.

To repeat for emphasis: at equilibrium, no purchaser and no supplier has an

incentive to change the price or quantity. In competitive market economies, actual

prices tend to be the equilibrium prices at which demand equals supply. This is

called the law of supply and demand. Note: this law does not mean that at every

moment of time the price is precisely at the intersection of the demand and supply

curves. Like the weight on a spring described above, the market may bounce around

a little bit when it is in the process of adjusting. What the law of supply and demand

does say is that when a market is out of equilibrium, there are predictable forces

for change.

68 ∂ CHAPTER 3 DEMAND, SUPPLY, AND PRICE

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!