02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

of $9,000, it sells 2 units; and at a price of $8,000, 3 units. The

third column of the table shows the total revenues at each of

these levels of production. The total revenues are just price multiplied

by quantity. The marginal revenue from producing an

extra unit (of 1,000 cubic yards) is just the difference between,

say, the revenues received at 3 units and 2 units or 2 units and

1 unit. Note that in each case, the marginal revenue is less than

the price.

Figure 12.4 shows the firm’s demand and marginal revenue

curves, using data from Table 12.1. At each level of output, the

marginal revenue curve lies below the demand curve. As can be

seen from the table, not only does price decrease as output

increases, but so does marginal revenue.

The output at which marginal revenue equals marginal cost—

the output chosen by the profit-maximizing monopolist—is

denoted by Q m . In our example, Q m = 4,000 cubic yards. When

the number of cubic yards increases from 3,000 to 4,000, the

marginal revenue is $4,000, and so is the marginal cost. At this level of output,

the price, p m , is $7,000 (per 1,000 cubic yards), which is considerably in excess

of marginal costs, $4,000. Total revenues, $28,000, are also in excess of total

costs, $24,000. 1

PRICE ($)

10,000

P m = 7,000

4,000

2,000

Figure 12.4

Marginal

cost curve

Demand

curve

0 1 2 3 Q m = 4

Average

cost curve

Marginal

revenue

curve

QUANTITY (THOUSANDS OF CUBIC YARDS)

DEMAND AND MARGINAL REVENUE

5 6

At each level of output, the marginal revenue curve lies below

the demand curve.

MONOPOLY PROFITS

Monopolists maximize their profits by setting marginal revenue equal to marginal

cost. The total level of monopoly profits can be seen in two ways, as shown in Figure

12.5. Panel A shows total revenues and total costs (from Table 12.1) for each level of

output of the ABC-ment Company. The difference between revenues and costs is

profits—the distance between the two curves. This distance is maximized at the

output Q m = 4,000 cubic yards. We can see that at this level of output, profits are

$4,000 ($28,000 − $24,000). Panel B calculates profits using the average cost diagram.

Total profits are equal to the profit per unit multiplied by the number of units

produced. The profit per unit is the difference between the unit price and the average

cost, and total monopoly profits is the shaded area ABCD. Again, the sum is

$4,000: ($7,000 − $6,000) × 4.

A monopolist enjoys an extra return because it has been able to reduce its output

and increase its price from the level that would have prevailed under competition.

This return is called a pure profit. Because these payments do not elicit greater

effort or production on the part of the monopolist (in fact, they derive from the

monopolist’s reducing the output from what it would be under competition), they

are also called monopoly rents.

1 In this example, the firm is indifferent to the choice between producing 3,000 or 4,000 cubic yards. If the marginal

cost of producing the extra output exceeds $4,000 by a little, then it will produce 3,000 cubic yards; if the

marginal cost is a little less than $4,000, then it will produce 4,000 cubic yards.

MONOPOLY OUTPUT ∂ 265

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!