02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

CONSUMPTION

Figure 8.9

Indifference

curves

E

Budget constraint

(slope = wage)

LEISURE

INDIFFERENCE CURVES AND

LEISURE-INCOME CHOICES

An individual will choose the combination of

leisure and income at E. Point A would be more

desirable, but it is not feasible. Other points on

the budget line or inside it are feasible, but they

lie on lower indifference curves and are therefore

not as desirable.

A

Appendix: Indifference Curves

and the Labor Supply Decision 2

This appendix investigates the labor supply decision using the indifference

curve approach applied in the appendix to Chapter 5 to the consumption

decision.

Figure 8.9 shows Tom’s budget constraint between leisure and consumption.

The slope of the budget constraint is the wage. The figure also shows

two indifference curves; each gives the combination of leisure and consumption

choices toward which Tom is indifferent. As usual, since people prefer

more of both consumption and leisure if that is possible, Tom will move to

the highest indifference curve he can attain—the one that is just tangent to

his budget constraint.

The slope of the indifference curve is the marginal rate of substitution

between leisure and consumption. It measures the amount of extra consumption

Tom requires to compensate him for forgoing one additional hour of

leisure. At the point of tangency between the indifference curve and the

budget constraint, point E, both have the same slope. That is, the marginal rate

of substitution equals the wage at this point.

As in the appendix in Chapter 5, we can easily see why Tom chooses this

point. Assume his marginal rate of substitution is $15 (dollars per hour), while

his wage is $20 (dollars per hour). If he works an hour more—gives up an

hour’s worth of leisure—his consumption goes up by $20. But to compensate

him for the forgone leisure, he requires only $15. Since he gets more than he

requires by working, he clearly prefers to work more.

DECIDING WHETHER TO WORK

Figure 8.10 shows how to use indifference curves to analyze how people decide

whether or not to work. Consider a low-wage individual facing a welfare system

that provides a fixed level of benefits to those whose income is below a threshold.

Benefits are cut off once income exceeds a certain level. The indifference curve I 0

is tangent to the budget constraint without welfare, and the point of tangency

is E 0 . The curve I 1 is the highest indifference curve consistent with the person

receiving welfare.

The three possible cases are illustrated in panels A, B, and C. In panel A, the

indifference curve through point E 0 , I 0 , is higher than the curve I 1 . The individual

chooses to work at E 0 and is unaffected by the welfare program. In panels B and C,

the person works sufficiently little to be eligible for welfare; that is, I 1 is higher than

I 0 , and so he chooses point E 1 . In panel B, the individual realizes that if he works

more, he will lose his welfare benefits. He earns just (little) enough to be eligible for

welfare. In panel C, the welfare system has only an income effect. If the welfare

benefits are large enough, the individual may choose not to work at all.

2 You will need to have read the appendix to Chapter 5 in order to follow this appendix.

188 ∂ CHAPTER 8 LABOR MARKETS

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!