02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Thinking Like an Economist

INCENTIVES AND THE REAL AFTER-TAX

RATE OF INTEREST

In other chapters we have emphasized that real values determine

incentives. Thus, decisions to save and invest respond

to real interest rates. So far, deriving the real interest rate

from the nominal interest rate has been straightforward:

subtract the rate of inflation from the nominal interest rate.

But for the sake of simplicity we have ignored another important

factor, the effect of taxation. In the absence of taxes on

interest income, a nominal interest rate of 2 percent and 0

percent inflation yields the same real return as a nominal interest

rate of 6 percent and 4 percent inflation. If nominal interest

income is taxed, then the relationship between the nominal

interest rate, inflation, and the real interest rate becomes more

complicated.

Suppose nominal interest income is taxed at a 25 percent

rate. If inflation is 0 percent and the nominal interest rate is

2 percent, the after-tax nominal return would be the 2 percent

return minus the taxes (.25 × 2 percent = 0.5 percent), leaving

an after-tax nominal return of 1.5 percent. With 0 percent

inflation, this is also the real return.

Now consider the situation when inflation rises to 4 percent.

If the nominal interest rate were to rise to 6 percent, the

after-tax return would be 6 percent minus taxes (.25 × 6 percent

= 1.5 percent), leaving a nominal after-tax return of 4.5 percent.

Since inflation was 4 percent, the real after-tax return is

only 0.5 percent! Even though the nominal interest rate rose

by the same amount as inflation, the real after-tax return fell.

To maintain the same 1.5 percent real after-tax return that

was obtained with 0 percent inflation, the nominal interest

rate would need to rise to 7.33 percent when inflation increases

to 4 percent. With a nominal return of 7.33 percent, the nominal

after-tax return would be 5.5 percent, and the real aftertax

return would be 1.5 percent. The nominal interest rate

must more than match increases in inflation in order to maintain

the same real return. In this example, if inflation increases

4 percent, the nominal interest rate must rise 5.33 percent.

The relationship would be different if countries designed

their tax systems to tax real returns rather than nominal

returns. In the case of 4 percent inflation, a nominal interest

rate of 6 percent would yield a real before-tax return of 2 percent

and an after-tax return of 1.5 percent, the same after-tax

return as was earned with 0 percent inflation and a 2 percent

nominal interest rate.

expenditures will be explained in Chapter 34; here we can note that it serves to reinforce

the negative effect on aggregate expenditures of a rise in the real rate. Thus the

basic effects of interest rates on the AE schedule in a closed economy will also be

observed when we are studying the determination of GDP in an open economy.

Wrap-Up

THE REAL INTEREST RATE AND

EQUILIBRIUM OUTPUT

A fall in the real rate of interest increases investment spending and household

purchases of durables and new homes. These increases shift the aggregate

expenditures schedule up, raising equilibrium output.

684 ∂ CHAPTER 30 AGGREGATE EXPENDITURES AND INCOME

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!