02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Thus, in Figure 8.5, at the price p 1 , the output is Q 1 (panel A), and the labor required

to produce that output (factor demand) is L 1 (panel B).

There is another way to derive the demand for a factor. If the firm hires one

more worker, for example, the extra (or marginal) cost to the firm is her wage. The

extra benefit of the worker is the additional revenue that the firm receives from selling

the output she produces. This is equal to the price at which the good sells multiplied

by the amount of extra output she produces. The extra output produced by

the worker is the marginal product of labor—the amount of output produced by the

last worker added by the firm. Thus the marginal benefit to the firm of adding an

extra worker is the price of the firm’s good multiplied by the marginal product of

labor. If adding an extra employee at the local Jiffy Lube enables the owner to handle

an extra 50 oil changes a month, and the price of each oil change is $25, then the

marginal benefit to the owner of adding the worker is $40 times 50, or $1,250 per

month. This dollar amount is called the value of the marginal product of labor.

While the marginal product of labor is measured in units of output (e.g., 50 oil changes

per month), the value of the marginal product is measured in dollars.

As long as the value of the marginal product of labor is greater than the marginal

cost of hiring the extra worker, the firm can increase its profits by hiring an

extra worker. In the Jiffy Lube example, as long as the added wage is less than $1,250

per month, it pays the owner to hire another worker. The firm hires labor up to the

point at which the value of the marginal product (the marginal benefit to the firm)

is equal to the price of labor, the wage (the marginal cost to the firm).

Using p for the price of the good, MPL for the marginal product

of labor, and w for the wage of the worker, we can write this

equilibrium condition as

value of marginal product = p × MPL = w = wage.

From this equilibrium condition, we can derive the demand

curve for labor. Figure 8.6 plots the value of the marginal product

of labor for each level of labor. Since the marginal product of labor

decreases as labor increases, the value of the marginal product also

decreases. When the wage is w 1 , the value of the marginal product

of labor equals the wage with a level of labor at L 1 . This is the firm’s

demand for labor at a wage w 1 . Thus, the curve giving the value of

the marginal product of labor at each level of employment is the

demand curve for labor.

It is easy to use this diagram to see the effect of an increase in

the price of the good the firm produces. In Figure 8.7, the higher

price increases the value of the marginal product of labor at each

level of employment, and it immediately follows that at each wage,

the demand for labor increases. The demand curve for labor shifts

to the right.

Thus, the demand for labor depends on both the wage and

the price the firm receives for the goods it sells. In fact, the demand

for labor depends only on the ratio of the two, as we will

now see.

WAGE (w )

w 2

w 1

Old demand curve

for labor

L 2 L 3 L 1

QUANTITY OF LABOR (L )

New demand curve

for labor (value of

marginal product at

higher price)

FIGURE 8.7

EFFECT OF PRICE CHANGE ON THE DEMAND

CURVE FOR LABOR

An increase in the price received by a firm shifts the value of

the marginal product of labor curve up, so that at each wage,

the demand for labor is increased. At wage w 1 , employment

rises from L 1 to L 4 ; at wage w 2 , employment rises from L 2

to L 3 .

L 4

FIRMS AND THE DEMAND FOR LABOR ∂ 183

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!