02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

investment increases the capital stock, thereby increasing potential GDP in

the future.

Evaluating Government Deficits

and Surpluses

We have seen that government deficits and surpluses have significant impacts.

Deficits reduce national saving, increase the real interest rate, and reduce investment,

and surpluses have the opposite effect. But while our analysis tells us what the

consequences of deficits and surpluses are, it does not tell us whether governments

should or should not run deficits.

Economists have traditionally argued that government borrowing, just like individual

borrowing, may or may not make sense, depending on the purpose for which

the funds have been borrowed. It makes sense to borrow to buy a house that you

will live in for many years or a car that you will drive for several years. Borrowing

is a way to spread the payments for the house or the car over time, so that you can

pay for the purchase as you use it. It also makes sense to borrow for an educational

degree that will lead to a higher-paying job in the future. But paying this year for a

vacation from two years ago makes no economic sense.

Countries are in a similar position. Borrowing to finance a road or a school that

will be used for many years may be quite appropriate; borrowing to pay for this

year’s government salaries or current operating costs poses real problems.

Governments in many countries—sometimes the dictators or corrupt regimes of

the past—have taken on more debt than they can comfortably pay off, forcing them

to raise taxes sharply and reduce citizens’ living standards. Others have simply

failed to repay what they owe, thereby jeopardizing their ability to borrow in

the future.

Financing government expenditures by borrowing rather than by raising taxes—

deficit financing—results in higher levels of private consumption in the short run, since

individuals’ taxes are lower. Thus, borrowing to finance government expenditures

can serve to shift the burden onto future generations. For example, the U.S. government

financed some of its World War II expenditures by borrowing rather than raising

taxes by the full amount necessary to cover the war effort. This debt was

discharged, in part, by taxes paid by workers long after the war ended. Thus, some

of the cost of the war was borne by the generation who entered the labor force after

the war. Since these later generations benefited from the Allied victory in World

War II, an argument can be made in this case that sharing the burden across

generations made sense. If governments borrow for spending that benefits only

the current generation, however, forcing future generations to share the cost is

less defensible.

There is another way that government borrowing shifts the burden of expenditures

onto future generations. When the economy is at full employment, more consumption

implies less saving. To maintain the economy at full employment, the real

interest rate must rise to balance saving and investment—and a higher equilibrium

EVALUATING GOVERNMENT DEFICITS AND SURPLUSES ∂ 557

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!