02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

telecommunications industry, other high-tech sectors, and export sectors is substantially

higher than that in other parts of the economy. Telecommunications deregulation

in the 1990s facilitated the movement of resources into that sector. Rapid

innovation in computer technology is affecting all sectors of the economy. Increasing

globalization will open up new opportunities for export growth. These changes are

contributing to the overall increase in productivity that the United States has

experienced since the mid-1990s.

TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE AND THE ROLE

OF IDEAS

While capital—both physical and human—is important for explaining the huge

changes in living standards over the past two hundred years, just having more

machines or better-educated workers cannot account for the truly amazing differences

between the economy in 1900 and the economy today. We are not producing

more of the same goods the economy produced in 1900; we are producing goods

that the people of 1900 never dreamed of. Instead of using more machines to produce

more horse-drawn carriages, we produce cars and airplanes. Instead of producing

more horseshoes, we produce tires and jogging shoes. Key to the whole growth

process, then, is technological progress—thinking up new ways to do old things and

new ways to do entirely new things. This means that ideas are central to explaining

economic growth. Indeed, economists estimate that as much as two-thirds of all

increases in productivity prior to 1973 were due to technological progress.

Investment increases the economy’s stock of physical capital, and education

leads to increases in human capital, but what leads to technological progress? To

understand the economics of technological progress, we need to start by considering

how ideas are different from such goods as a laptop computer or a piece of chocolate

cake. These goods are rivalrous; if I eat that piece of chocolate cake, you can’t.

But ideas are different. If both you and your roommate are taking economics, both

of you can use an idea like the law of supply and demand. If your roommate does

her homework first, the idea is still available to you when you get around to studying.

When Tim Berners-Lee, Robert Cailliau, and their colleagues at the European

particle physics center (CERN) in Geneva, Switzerland, invented the World Wide

Web and hypertext markup language, or HTML, in 1990, programmers from around

the world could use their ideas. If you use HTML to construct a Web page, the idea

is still also available to others—it is a nonrivalrous good. This is a key property of

ideas; they cannot be used up.

One of the major differences between the economy today and in 1900 is the routine

nature of the change brought about by new ideas. This technological progress

is accomplished through the activities of thousands of entrepreneurs and innovators,

particularly in the computer industry, and thousands of scientists and engineers

engaged in large-scale research projects in the business, government, and

university sectors. Much of modern research is centered in huge laboratories, employing

large numbers of people. While the government runs some of these—such as

the Brookhaven, Argonne, and Lawrence laboratories that carry out research in

basic physics—many are private, as was Bell Laboratories, where the transistor and

Modern textile manufacturing bears

little resemblance to the traditional

hand loom, which is still used in

underdeveloped areas such as

Darjeeling, India.

EXPLAINING PRODUCTIVITY ∂ 593

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!