02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

AGGREGATE EXPENDITURES (AE )

The aggregate

expenditures

schedule shifts

up by the change

in G (∆G )

45°

Figure 30.7

New aggregate

expenditures

schedule (AE 1

)

Y 0

Aggregate

expenditures

= output

Y 1

INCOME = OUTPUT (Y )

THE EFFECT OF AN INCREASE IN

GOVERNMENT PURCHASES

Original

aggregate

expenditures

schedule

(AE 0

)

Government purchases (G ) are one of the components

of aggregate expenditures. An increase in

government purchases shifts the aggregate

expenditures schedule up by the amount of the

increase. Because of the multiplier effect, the

increase in equilibrium output, Y 1 − Y 0 , is greater

than the increase in government purchases, ∆G.

Third, changing perceptions of risk or of future economic conditions affect

investment expenditures. Their influence helps account for the volatility

of investment, and they can be added to our list of factors that shift the

aggregate expenditures schedule.

Government Purchases

The third component of aggregate expenditures is government purchases.

In later chapters, when we discuss fiscal policy in the United States, we will

usually focus on the expenditure and tax policies of the federal government.

However, this category consists of the purchases of goods and services by all

levels of government—federal, state, and local. In fact, of the total government

purchases of roughly $2 trillion (about 18 percent of GDP), only about

one-third—under $700 billion—are made by the federal government. Its total

expenditures of about $3 trillion exceed those by state and local governments,

but a large fraction of federal expenditures are for programs such as Social

Security that do not directly purchase goods and services. The largest

component of federal government purchases is defense, equal to roughly

two-thirds of the total.

At this point in our analysis, it is useful to assume that total government

purchases do not vary with income but instead are simply fixed—say, at $2

trillion. Earlier, we learned that taxes vary with income, so government revenue

will rise and fall as income fluctuates. But because the government can

borrow (run a deficit) when tax revenues are less than expenditures, and

repay its debt when tax revenues exceed expenditures, government spending

does not need to move in lockstep with tax revenues. In later chapters we

will study in greater detail the role of fiscal policy, government expenditures,

and tax policies. For now, though, we will assume that government purchases are

fixed (in real terms).

Government purchases (G) are one component of aggregate expenditures. An

increase in G will raise aggregate expenditures at each level of total income. This

rise shifts the AE schedule up by the amount of the increase in G, as Figure 30.7

shows. Equilibrium again occurs at the intersection of the aggregate expenditures

schedule and the 45-degree line. The total increase in equilibrium output depends

on the size of the change in G and on the multiplier.

Net Exports

The analysis so far has ignored the important role of international trade. Such an

omission is appropriate for a closed economy, an economy that neither imports

nor exports, but not for an open economy, one actively engaged in international

trade. Today, the United States and other industrialized economies are very much

open economies.

676 ∂ CHAPTER 30 AGGREGATE EXPENDITURES AND INCOME

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!