02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

EFFICIENCY AND THE STOCK MARKET

Most people do not think they can wander over to the racetrack and make a fortune.

They are not so skeptical about the stock market. They believe that even if

they themselves cannot sit down with the Wall Street Journal or browse an online

broker’s site and pick out all the best stocks, someone who studies the stock market

for a living could do so. But economists startled the investment community in the early

1960s by pointing out that choosing successful stocks is no easier—and no harder—

than choosing the fastest horses.

The efficient market theory explains this discrepancy in views. When economists

speak of an efficient market, they are referring to one in which relevant information

is widely known and quickly distributed to all participants. To oversimplify

a bit, they envision a stock market where all investors have access to Barron’s and

Fortune magazines or to one of the many Internet sites devoted to providing good information

about businesses, and where government requires businesses to disclose

certain information to the public. Thus, each stock’s expected return, its risk, its

tax treatment, and so on will be fully known by all investors. Because participants

have all the relevant information, asset prices will reflect that knowledge.

But it turns out that this broad dissemination of information is not only unrealistic

but also unnecessary for the stock market to be efficient. Economists have

shown that efficient markets do not require that all participants have information.

If enough participants have information, prices will move as if the whole market had

the information. All it takes is a few people knowledgeable enough to recognize a

good deal (bad deal), and prices will quickly be bid up (or down) to levels that reflect

complete information. And if prices reflect complete information, then even uninformed

investors, purchasing at current prices, will reap the benefit; while they

cannot “beat the market,” neither do they have to worry about being “cheated” by

an overpriced security.

You cannot beat an efficient market any more than you can beat the track. You

can only get lucky in it. All the research done by the many big brokerage houses

and individual investors adds up to a market that is in some respects like a casino.

This is the irony of the view, held by most economists, that the stock market is an

efficient one. If you are trying to make money in an efficient stock market, it is not

enough to choose companies that you expect will be successful in the future. If you

expect a company to be successful and everyone else also expects it to be successful,

given the available information, then the price of the shares in that company

will already be high. The only way to make abnormally high profits on stock purchases

is to pick companies that will surprise the market by doing better than is generally

expected. There are always such companies—the problem is to identify them

before everyone else! When Microsoft shares first became available to the public

in March 1968, they sold for 19 cents. By 2000, those shares were worth $58 dollars

each. Early investors in technology stocks made enormous returns because

technology firms did better than anyone had initially expected. Because of the success

of many of these companies during the late 1990s, whenever a new one would

“go public”—sells shares to the public for the first time—the price would often

jump immediately to a very high level. The initial public offering of Google in 2004

exemplified this phenomenon. An investor buying the stock at high market prices

882 ∂ CHAPTER 39 A STUDENT’S GUIDE TO INVESTING

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!