02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

years, many countries have attempted to reduce the influence of elected politicians

on monetary policy for just this reason.

Rules Versus Discretion Critics of intervention claim that historically, whether

because of politically motivated decisions or simply because of the lags described earlier,

government has actually exacerbated the economy’s fluctuations. When the

government attempts to dampen a boom, its policies aimed at reducing demand

take effect just as the economy is weakening, reinforcing the downward movement.

Conversely, when the government attempts to stimulate the economy, the increase

in demand kicks in as the economy is strengthening on its own, thereby igniting

inflation. Critics of government action such as Milton Friedman thus conclude that

better outcomes would result if policies were based on simple rules rather than on

the discretion of the government policymakers. Friedman proposed that the government

should expand the money supply at a constant rate rather than actively

tailor monetary policy to economic events in the hopes of stabilizing the economy.

According to Friedman and others, by sticking to rules, the government would eliminate

a major source of uncertainty and instability in the economy—uncertainty

about future government policies.

A second argument for rules stresses the importance of commitment. A government

might promise to keep inflation low. But as an election nears, politicians

might be tempted to try to expand the economy a bit to improve their reelection

chances, even though this action will lead to lower unemployment only temporarily

while leaving the economy with higher inflation. Knowing that the government will

face this temptation, individuals will not believe the initial promise to be steadfast;

they will anticipate higher inflation in the future. As we learned in Chapter 37, a rise

in inflation expectations increases current inflation. Lack of credible commitment

to a low-inflation policy may result in higher-than-desired inflation without even a

temporary gain of lower unemployment.

The uncertainty about whether a government will actually carry out a promised

course of action is called the problem of dynamic inconsistency. This problem

arises in many contexts. A city may promise to keep taxes low in order to

attract a new shopping mall. Once the mall is built, however, the city may find it

an irresistible source of tax revenues, despite earlier promises. Anticipating this

change of course, the developers may decide not to build the mall in the first

place.

For another example of dynamic inconsistency, consider the case of a final

exam. Because its purpose is to provide students with an incentive to study the

course material, teachers almost always think it good policy to announce a scheduled

final exam. By the morning of the exam, it is too late to influence whether students

have studied or not—the only thing a teacher has to look forward to is grading

all those exams. So it makes sense to cancel the test. But if students anticipate

this reprieve, they will not study, and announcing that there will be an exam will

no longer have any effect. Few teachers cancel final exams, because they know

that if they do it once, their future students will not prepare for an exam they

expect to be canceled. The teacher has a reputation to protect. Similarly, the desire

to maintain a reputation for doing what they promise can help governments fulfill

their promises.

846 ∂ CHAPTER 38 CONTROVERSIES IN MACROECONOMIC POLICY

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!