02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Before one large company can acquire or merge with a competitor, it must convince

the government that the acquisition would not seriously interfere with the

overall competitiveness of the market.

CURBING RESTRICTIVE PRACTICES

In addition to promoting competition by limiting the degree of concentration within

an industry, the government works to limit restrictive practices. The history here

begins with the 1914 Federal Trade Commission Act. The first ten words of the act

read: “Unfair methods of competition in commerce are hereby declared unlawful.”

President Woodrow Wilson defined the purpose of the new commission as being to

“plead the voiceless consumer’s case.” Since then, a number of laws have been passed

by Congress to specify what is “unfair.”

Many of the restrictive practices targeted by the government involve the relations

between a firm and its distributors and suppliers. Such practices include tie-ins,

exclusive dealing, and price discrimination. We have already encountered all three

in Chapter 12. Tie-ins require a consumer to purchase additional items when she

buys a product. In exclusive dealing, a producer says to a firm that wants to sell its

product, “If you sell my product, you cannot sell that of my rival.” Price discrimination

entails charging different customers different prices on grounds unrelated to

the costs of serving those customers. The Robinson-Patman Act of 1936 strengthened

the provisions outlawing price discrimination, making it easier to convict firms

engaged in the practice. Other practices discussed in Chapter 12 designed to deter

entry or promote collusion are illegal as well.

The precise definition of an illegal restrictive practice has changed over time with

varying court interpretations of the antitrust laws. Some practices are illegal per se—

firms conspiring to fix prices, for example. In 1961, General Electric, Westinghouse, and

other producers of electrical equipment were found guilty of such conspiracy. More

recently, several huge price-fixing cases were prosecuted successfully, most notably

one against ADM (Archer Daniel Midland) involving lysine, citric acid, and highfructose

corn syrup. The corporations paid more than $100 million in fines, and some

of their officials went to prison. Most practices, however, are not so clear-cut, and today

a “rule of reason” prevails: they are acceptable if they can be shown to be reasonable

business procedures, designed to promote economic efficiency. The efficiency

gains are balanced against the higher prices resulting from the reduced competition.

Consider the example of Budweiser beer, which delivers its product through distributors.

In any area, there is only one distributor, and the distributors are not

allowed to compete against one another. The New York attorney general has argued

that this system, by restricting competition, raises prices. Anheuser-Busch has

replied that the system of exclusive territories enhances the efficiency with which

beer is delivered and is necessary to ensure that customers receive fresh beer. They

have maintained that their distribution system satisfies the rule of reason, and thus

far their view has prevailed in the courts.

States have also been accused of adopting laws that restrict competition in ways

designed to favor in-state firms. In December 2004, the U.S. Supreme Court heard

304 ∂ CHAPTER 13 GOVERNMENT POLICIES TOWARD COMPETITION

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!